And then the conclusion is drawn3, that the best custom-house regulation would be that which should give the utmost possible facility to the entry of raw material, and oppose the greatest obstacles to articles which have received their first manipulation by labor.
No sophism4 of political economy is more widely spread than the foregoing. It supports not only the protectionists, but, much more, and above all, the pretended liberalists. This is to be regretted; for the worst which can happen to a good cause is not to be severely5 attacked, but to be badly defended.
Commercial freedom will probably have the fate of all freedom; it will not be introduced into our laws until after it has taken possession of our minds. But if it be true that a reform must be generally understood, in order that it may be solidly established, it follows that nothing can retard6 it so much as that which misleads public opinion; and what is more likely to mislead it than those writings which seem to favor freedom by upholding the doctrines8 of monopoly?
[137]
Several years ago, three large cities of France—Lyons, Bordeaux, and Havre—were greatly agitated9 against the restrictive policy. The nation, and indeed all Europe, was moved at seeing a banner raised, which they supposed to be that of free trade. Alas10! it was still the banner of monopoly; of a monopoly a little more niggardly11, and a great deal more absurd, than that which they appeared to wish to overturn. Owing to the sophism which we are about to unveil, the petitioners12 merely reproduced the doctrine7 of protection to national labor, adding to it, however, another folly13.
What is, in effect, the prohibitive system? Let us listen to the protectionist: "Labor constitutes the wealth of a people, because it alone creates those material things which our necessities demand, and because general comfort depends upon these."
This is the principle.
"But this abundance must be the product of national labor. Should it be the product of foreign labor, national labor would stop at once."
This is the mistake. (See the close of the last chapter.)
"What shall be done, then, in an agricultural and manufacturing country?"
This is the question.
"Restrict its market to the products of its own soil, and its own industry."
This is the end proposed.
"And for this end, restrain by prohibitive duties the entrance of the products of the industry of other nations."
These are the means.
[138]
Let us reconcile with this system that of the petition from Bordeaux.
It divided merchandise into three classes:
"The first includes articles of food, and raw material free from all human labor. A wise economy would require that this class should not be taxed."
Here there is no labor; consequently no protection.
"The second is composed of articles which have undergone some preparation. This preparation warrants us in charging it with some tax."
Here protection commences, because, according to the petitioners, national labor commences.
"The third comprises perfected articles which can in no way serve national labor; we consider these the most taxable."
Here, labor, and with it protection, reach their maximum.
The petitioners assert that foreign labor injures national labor; this is the error of the prohibitive school.
They demanded that the French market should be restricted to French labor; this is the end of the prohibitive system.
They insisted that foreign labor should be subject to restriction14 and taxation15; these are the means of the prohibitive system.
What difference, then, is it possible to discover between the petitioners of Bordeaux and the advocate of American restriction? One alone: the greater or less extent given to the word labor.
The protectionist extends it to everything—so he wishes to protect everything.
"Labor constitutes all the wealth of a people," says [139] he; "to protect national industry, all national industry, manufacturing industry, all manufacturing industry, is the idea which should always be kept before the people." The petitioners saw no labor excepting that of manufacturers; so they would admit that alone to the favors of protection. They said:
"Raw material is devoid16 of all human labor. For that reason we should not tax it. Fabricated articles can no longer occupy national labor. We consider them the most taxable."
We are not inquiring whether protection to national labor is reasonable. The protectionist and the Bordelais agree upon this point, and we, as has been seen in the preceding chapters, differ from both.
The question is to ascertain17 which of the two—the protectionists or the raw-materialists of Bordeaux—give its just acceptation to the word "labor."
Now, upon this ground, it must be said, the protectionist is, by all odds18, right; for observe the dialogue which might take place between them:
The Protectionist: "You agree that national labor ought to be protected. You agree that no foreign labor can be introduced into our market without destroying therein an equal amount of our national labor. Yet you assert that there is a host of merchandise possessed19 of value (since it sells), which is, however, free from human labor. And, among other things, you name wheat, corn, meats, cattle, lard, salt, iron, brass20, lead, coal, wool, furs, seeds, etc. If you can prove to me that the value of these things is not due to labor, I will agree that it is useless to protect them. But, again, if I demonstrate to you that there is as much labor in a [140] hundred dollars' worth of wool as in a hundred dollars' worth of cloth, you must acknowledge that protection is as much due to the one as to the other. Now, why is this bag of wool worth a hundred dollars? Is it not because that sum is the price of production? And is the price of production anything but that which it has been necessary to distribute in wages, salaries, manual labor, interest, to all the workmen and capitalists who have concurred21 in producing the article?"
The Raw-Materialist: "It is true, that in regard to wool, you may be right. But a bag of wheat, an ingot of iron, a quintal of coal—are they the produce of labor? Did not Nature create them?"
The Protectionist: "Without doubt Nature creates the elements of all things; but it is labor which produces their value. I was wrong myself in saying that labor creates material objects, and this faulty phrase has led the way to many other errors. It does not belong to man, either manufacturer or cultivator, to create, to make something out of nothing; if, by production, we understand creation, all our labors22 will be unproductive; that of merchants more so than any other, except, perhaps, that of law-makers. The farmer has no claim to have created wheat, but he may claim to have created its value: he has transformed into wheat substances which in no wise resembled it, by his own labor with that of his ploughmen and reapers23. What more does the miller24 effect who converts it into flour, the baker25 who turns it into bread? Because man must clothe himself in cloth, a host of operations is necessary. Before the intervention26 of any human labor, the true raw materials of this product (cloth) are air, water, [141] gas, light, the chemical substances which must enter into its composition. These are truly the raw materials which are untouched by human labor; therefore, they are of no value, and I do not think of protecting them. But a first labor converts these substances into hay, straw, etc., a second into wool, a third into thread, a fourth into cloth, a fifth into clothing—who will dare to say that every step in this work is not labor, from the first stroke of the plough, which begins, to the last stroke of the needle, which terminates it? And because, in order to secure more celerity and perfection in the accomplishment27 of a definite work, such as a garment, the labors are divided among several classes of industry, you wish, by an arbitrary distinction, that the order of succession of these labors should be the only reason for their importance; so much so that the first shall not deserve even the name of labor, and that the last work pre-eminently, shall alone be worthy28 of the favors of protection!"
The Raw-Materialist: "Yes, we begin to see that wheat no more than wool is entirely29 devoid of human labor; but, at least, the agriculturist has not, like the manufacturer, done all by himself and his workmen; Nature aids him, and if there is labor, it is not all labor in the wheat."
The Protectionist: "But all its value is in the labor it has cost. I admit that Nature has assisted in the material formation of wheat. I admit even that it may be exclusively her work; but confess that I have controlled it by my labor; and when I sell you some wheat, observe this well: that it is not the work of Nature for which I make you pay, but my own; and, [142] on your supposition, manufactured articles would be no more the product of labor than agricultural ones. Does not the manufacturer, too, rely upon Nature to second him? Does he not avail himself of the weight of the atmosphere in aid of the steam-engine, as I avail myself of its humidity in aid of the plough? Did he create the laws of gravitation, of correlation30 of forces, of affinities31?"
The Raw-Materialist: "Come, let the wool go too. But coal is assuredly the work, and the exclusive work, of Nature, unaided by any human labor."
The Protectionist: "Yes, Nature made coal, but labor makes its value. Coal had no value during the thousands of years during which it was hidden, unknown, a hundred feet below the soil. It was necessary to look for it there—that is a labor: it was necessary to transport it to market; that is another labor: and once more, the price which you pay for it in the market is nothing else than the remuneration for these labors of digging and transportation."
We see that thus far the protectionist has all the advantage on his side; that the value of raw material, as well as that of manufactured material, represents the expense of production, that is to say, of labor; that it is impossible to conceive of a material possessed of value while totally unindebted to human labor; that the distinction which the raw-materialists make is wholly futile32, in theory; that, as a basis for an unequal division of favors, it would be iniquitous33 in practice; because the result would be that one-third of the people, engaged in manufactures, would obtain the sweets of monopoly, for the reason that they produced [143] by labor, while the other two-thirds, that is to say the agriculturists, would be abandoned to competition, under pretext34 that they produced without labor.
It will be urged that it is of more advantage to a nation to import the materials called raw, whether they are or are not the product of labor, and to export manufactured articles.
This is a strongly accredited35 opinion.
"The more abundant raw materials are," said the petition from Bordeaux, "the more manufactories are multiplied and extended." It said again, that "raw material opens an unlimited36 field of labor to the inhabitants of the country from which it is imported."
"Raw material," said the other petition, that from Havre, "being the aliment of labor, must be submitted to a different system, and admitted at once at the lowest duty." The same petition would have the protection on manufactured articles reduced, not one after another, but at an undetermined time; not to the lowest duty, but to twenty per cent.
"Among other articles which necessity requires to be abundant and cheap," said the third petition, that from Lyons, "the manufacturers name all raw material."
This all rests on an illusion. We have seen that all value represents labor. Now, it is true that labor increases ten-fold, sometimes a hundred-fold, the value of a rough product, that is to say, expands ten-fold, a hundred-fold, the products of a nation. Thence it is reasoned, "The production of a bale of cotton causes workmen of all classes to earn one hundred dollars only. The conversion37 of this bale into lace collars raises their profits to ten thousand dollars; and will [144] you dare to say that the nation is not more interested in encouraging labor worth ten thousand than that worth one hundred dollars?"
We forget that international exchanges, no more than individual exchanges, work by weight or measure. We do not exchange a bale of cotton for a bale of lace collars, nor a pound of wool in the grease for a pound of wool in cashmere; but a certain value of one of these things for an equal value of the other. Now to barter38 equal value against equal value is to barter equal work against equal work. It is not true, then, that the nation which gives for a hundred dollars cashmere or collars, gains more than the nation which delivers for a hundred dollars wool or cotton.
In a country where no law can be adopted, no impost39 established, without the consent of those whom this law is to govern, the public cannot be robbed without being first deceived. Our ignorance is the "raw material" of all extortion which is practised upon us, and we may be sure in advance that every sophism is the forerunner40 of a spoliation. Good public, when you see a sophism, clap your hand on your pocket; for that is certainly the point at which it aims. What was the secret thought which the shipowners of Bordeaux and of Havre, and the manufacturers of Lyons, conceived in this distinction between agricultural products and manufactured articles?
"It is principally in this first class (that which comprehends raw material unmodified by human labor)," said the Raw-Materialists of Bordeaux, "that the chief aliment of our merchant marine41 is found. At the outset, a wise economy would require that this class [145] should not be taxed. The second (articles which have received some preparation) may be charged; the third (articles on which no more work has to be done) we consider the most taxable."
"Consider," said those of Havre, "that it is indispensable to reduce all raw materials one after another to the lowest rate, in order that industry may successively bring into operation the naval42 forces which will furnish to it its first and indispensable means of labor." The manufacturers could not in exchange of politeness be behind the ship-owners; so the petition from Lyons demanded the free introduction of raw material, "in order to prove," said they, "that the interests of manufacturing towns are not always opposed to those of maritime43 ones!"
True; but it must be said that both interests were, understood as the petitioners understood them, terribly opposed to the interests of the country, of agriculture, and of consumers.
See, then, where you would come out! See the end of these subtle economical distinctions! You would legislate44 against allowing perfected produce to traverse the ocean, in order that the much more expensive transportation of rough materials, dirty, loaded with waste matter, may offer more employment to our merchant service, and put our naval force into wider operation. This is what these petitioners termed a wise economy. Why did they not demand that the firs of Russia should be brought to them with their branches, bark, and roots; the gold of California in its mineral state, and the hides from Buenos Ayres still attached to the bones of the tainted45 skeleton?
[146]
Industry, the navy, labor, have for their end, the general good, the public good. To create a useless industry, in order to favor superfluous46 transportation; to feed superfluous labor, not for the good of the public, but for the expense of the public—this is to realize a veritable begging the question. Work, in itself, is not a desirable thing; its result is; all work without result is a loss. To pay sailors for carrying useless waste matter across the sea is like paying them for skipping stones across the surface of the water. So we arrive at this result: that all economical sophisms, despite their infinite variety, have this in common, that they confound the means with the end, and develop one at the expense of the other.
点击收听单词发音
1 advantageous | |
adj.有利的;有帮助的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
2 labor | |
n.劳动,努力,工作,劳工;分娩;vi.劳动,努力,苦干;vt.详细分析;麻烦 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
3 drawn | |
v.拖,拉,拔出;adj.憔悴的,紧张的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
4 sophism | |
n.诡辩 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
5 severely | |
adv.严格地;严厉地;非常恶劣地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
6 retard | |
n.阻止,延迟;vt.妨碍,延迟,使减速 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
7 doctrine | |
n.教义;主义;学说 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
8 doctrines | |
n.教条( doctrine的名词复数 );教义;学说;(政府政策的)正式声明 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
9 agitated | |
adj.被鼓动的,不安的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
10 alas | |
int.唉(表示悲伤、忧愁、恐惧等) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
11 niggardly | |
adj.吝啬的,很少的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
12 petitioners | |
n.请求人,请愿人( petitioner的名词复数 );离婚案原告 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
13 folly | |
n.愚笨,愚蠢,蠢事,蠢行,傻话 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
14 restriction | |
n.限制,约束 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
15 taxation | |
n.征税,税收,税金 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
16 devoid | |
adj.全无的,缺乏的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
17 ascertain | |
vt.发现,确定,查明,弄清 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
18 odds | |
n.让步,机率,可能性,比率;胜败优劣之别 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
19 possessed | |
adj.疯狂的;拥有的,占有的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
20 brass | |
n.黄铜;黄铜器,铜管乐器 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
21 concurred | |
同意(concur的过去式与过去分词形式) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
22 labors | |
v.努力争取(for)( labor的第三人称单数 );苦干;详细分析;(指引擎)缓慢而困难地运转 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
23 reapers | |
n.收割者,收获者( reaper的名词复数 );收割机 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
24 miller | |
n.磨坊主 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
25 baker | |
n.面包师 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
26 intervention | |
n.介入,干涉,干预 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
27 accomplishment | |
n.完成,成就,(pl.)造诣,技能 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
28 worthy | |
adj.(of)值得的,配得上的;有价值的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
29 entirely | |
ad.全部地,完整地;完全地,彻底地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
30 correlation | |
n.相互关系,相关,关连 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
31 affinities | |
n.密切关系( affinity的名词复数 );亲近;(生性)喜爱;类同 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
32 futile | |
adj.无效的,无用的,无希望的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
33 iniquitous | |
adj.不公正的;邪恶的;高得出奇的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
34 pretext | |
n.借口,托词 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
35 accredited | |
adj.可接受的;可信任的;公认的;质量合格的v.相信( accredit的过去式和过去分词 );委托;委任;把…归结于 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
36 unlimited | |
adj.无限的,不受控制的,无条件的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
37 conversion | |
n.转化,转换,转变 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
38 barter | |
n.物物交换,以货易货,实物交易 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
39 impost | |
n.进口税,关税 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
40 forerunner | |
n.前身,先驱(者),预兆,祖先 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
41 marine | |
adj.海的;海生的;航海的;海事的;n.水兵 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
42 naval | |
adj.海军的,军舰的,船的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
43 maritime | |
adj.海的,海事的,航海的,近海的,沿海的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
44 legislate | |
vt.制定法律;n.法规,律例;立法 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
45 tainted | |
adj.腐坏的;污染的;沾污的;感染的v.使变质( taint的过去式和过去分词 );使污染;败坏;被污染,腐坏,败坏 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
46 superfluous | |
adj.过多的,过剩的,多余的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
欢迎访问英文小说网 |