1. Money and Plan
We have attempted to examine the Soviet2 regime in the cross-section of currency. These two problems, state and money, have a number of traits in common, for they both reduce themselves in the last analysis to the problem of problems: productivity of labor. State compulsion like money compulsion is an inheritance from the class society, which is incapable3 of defining the relations of man by man except in the form of fetishes, churchly or secular4, after appointing to defend them the most alarming of all fetishes, the state, with a great knife between its teeth. In a communist society, the state and money will disappear. Their gradual dying away ought consequently to begin under socialism. We shall be able to speak of the actual triumph of socialism only at that historical moment when the state turns into a semi-state, and money begins to lose its magic power. This will mean that socialism, having freed itself from capitalist fetishes, is beginning to create a more lucid5, free and worthy6 relation among men. Such characteristically anarchist7 demands as the “abolition8” of money, “abolition” of wages, or “liquidation9” of the state and family, possess interest merely as models of mechanical thinking. Money cannot be arbitrarily “abolished”, nor the state and the old family “liquidated11.” They have to exhaust their historic mission, evaporate, and fall away. The deathblow to money fetishism will be struck only upon that stage when the steady growth of social wealth has made us bipeds forget our miserly attitude toward every excess minute of labor, and our humiliating fear about the size of our ration12. Having lost its ability to bring happiness or trample13 men in the dust, money will turn into mere10 bookkeeping receipts for the convenience of statisticians and for planning purposes. In the still more distant future, probably these receipts will not be needed. But we can leave this question entirely14 to posterity15, who will be more intelligent than we are.
The nationalization of the means of production and credit, the co-operative or state-izing of internal trade, the monopoly of foreign trade, the collectivization of agriculture, the law on inheritance – set strict limits upon the personal accumulation of money and hinder its conversion16 into private capital (usurious, commercial and industrial). These functions of money, however, bound up as they are with exploitation, are not liquidated at the beginning of a proletarian revolution, but in a modified form are transferred to the state, the universal merchant, creditor17 and industrialist18. At the same time the more elementary functions of money, as measures of value, means of exchange and medium of payment, are not only preserved, but acquire a broader field of action than they had under capitalism19.
Administrative20 planning has sufficiently21 revealed its power – but therewith also the limits of its power. An a priori economic plan – above all in a backward country with 170 million population, and a profound contradiction between city and country – is not a fixed22 gospel, but a rough working hypothesis which must be verified and reconstructed in the process of its fulfillment. We might indeed lay down a rule: the more “accurately23” an administrative task is fulfilled, the worse is the economic leadership. For the regulation and application of plans two levers are needed: the political lever, in the form of a real participation24 in leadership of the interested masses themselves, a thing which is unthinkable without Soviet democracy; and a financial lever, in the form of a real testing out of a priori calculations with the help of a universal equivalent, a thing that is unthinkable without a stable money system.
The role of money in the Soviet economy is not only unfinished but, as we have said, still has a long growth ahead. The transitional epoch25 between capitalism and socialism taken as a whole does not mean a cutting down of trade, but, on the contrary, its extraordinary extension. All branches of industry transform themselves and grow. New ones continually arise, and all are compelled to define their relations to one another both quantitatively26 and qualitatively27. The liquidation of the consummatory peasant economy, and at the same time of the shut-in family life, means a transfer to the sphere of social interchange, and ipso facto money circulation, of all the labor energy which was formerly28 expended30 within the limits of the peasant’s yard, or within the walls of his private dwelling31. All products and services begin for the first time in history to be exchanged for one another.
On the other hand, a successful socialist33 construction is unthinkable without including in the planned system the direct personal interests of the producer and consumer, their egoism, – which in its turn may reveal itself fruitfully only if it has in its service the customary reliable and flexible instrument, money. The raising of the productivity of labor and bettering of the quality of its products is quite unattainable without an accurate measure freely penetrating34 into all the cells of industry – that is, without a stable unit of currency. Hence it is clear that in the transitional economy, as also under capitalism, the sole authentic35 money is that based upon gold. All other money is only a substitute. To be sure, the Soviet state has in its hand at the same time the mass of commodities and the machinery36 for printing money. However, this does not change the situation. Administrative manipulations in the sphere of commodity prices do not in the slightest degree create, or replace, a stable money unit either for domestic or foreign trade. Deprived of an independent basis – that is, a gold basis – the money system of the Soviet union, like that of a number of capitalist countries, has necessarily a shut-in character. For the world market the ruble does not exist. If the Soviet union can endure the adverse37 aspects of this money system more easily than Germany and Italy, it is only in part due to the natural wealth of the country. Only this makes it possible not to struggle in the clutches of autarchy. The historic task, however, is not merely not avoid strangling, but to create face to face with the highest achievements of the world market a powerful economy, rational through and through, which will guarantee the greatest saving of time and consequently the highest flowering of culture.
The dynamic Soviet economy, passing as it does through continual technical revolutions and large-scale experiments, needs more than any other continual testing by means of a stable measure of value. Theoretically there cannot be the slightest doubt that if the Soviet economy had possessed38 a gold ruble, the result of the five-year plan would be incomparably more favorable than they are now. Of course you cannot “poss the impossible” [Ha nyet cuda nyet]. But you must not make a virtue39 of necessity, for that leads in turn to additional economic mistakes and losses.
2. “Socialist” Inflation
The history of the Soviet currency is not only a history of economic difficulties, successes and failures, but also a history of the zigzags40 of bureaucratic41 thought.
The restoration of the ruble in 1922-24, in connection with the transfer to the NEP, was directly bound up with the restoration of the “norms of bourgeois42 right” in the distribution of objects of consumption. So long as the course toward the well-to-do farmer continued, the chervonetz was an object of governmental concern. During the first period of the five-year plan, on the contrary, all the sluices43 of inflation were opened. From 0.7 billion rubles at the beginning of 1925, the total issue of currency had arisen by the beginning of 1928 to the comparatively modest sum of 1.7 billions, which is approximately comparable to the paper money circulation of tzarist Russia on the eve of the war – but this, of course, without its former metallic44 basis. The subsequent curve of inflation from year to year is depicted45 in the following feverish46 series: 2.0 – 2.8 – 4.3 – 5.5 – 8.4! The final figure 8.4 billion rubles was reached at the beginning of 1933. After that came the years of reconsideration and retreat: 6.9 – 7.7 – 7.9 billion (1935). The ruble of 1924, equal in the official exchange to 13 francs, had been reduced in November 1935 to 3 francs – that is, to less than a fourth of its value, or almost as much as the French franc was reduced as a result of the war. Both parties, the old and the new, are very conditional47 in character; the purchasing power of the ruble in world prices now hardly equal 1.5 francs. Nevertheless the scale of devaluation shows with what dizzy speed the Soviet valuta was sliding downhill until 1934.
In the full flight of his economic adventurism, Stalin promised to send the NEP – that is, market relations – “to the devil.” The entire press wrote, as in 1918, about the final replacement49 of merchant sale by “direct socialist distribution”, the external sigh of which was the food card. At the same time, inflation was categorically rejected as a phenomenon inconsistent with the Soviet system.
“The stability of the Soviet valuta,” said Stalin in 1933, “is guaranteed primarily by the immense quantity of commodities in the hands of the state put in circulation at stable prices.”
Notwithstanding the fact that this enigmatical aphorism50 received neither development nor elucidation51 (partly indeed because of this), it became a fundamental law of the Soviet theory of money – or, more accurately, of that very inflation which it rejected. The chervonetz proved thereafter to be not a universal equivalent, but only the universal shadow of an “immense” quantity of commodities. And like all shadows, it possessed the right to shorten and lengthen52 itself. If this consoling doctrine53 made any sense at all, it was only this: the Soviet money has ceased to be money; it serves no longer as a measure of value; “stable prices” are designated by the state power; the chervonetz is only a conventional label of the planned economy – that is, a universal distribution card. In a word, socialism has triumphed “finally and irrevocably.”
The most utopian views of the period of military communism were thus restored on a new economic basis – a little higher, to be sure, but alas54 still inadequate55 for the liquidation of money circulation. The ruling circles were completely possessed by the opinion that with a planned economy inflation is not to be feared. This means approximately that if you possess a compass there is no danger in a leaking ship. In reality, currency inflation, inevitably56 producing a credit inflation, entails57 a substitution of fictitious58 for real magnitudes, and corrodes59 the planned economy from within.
It is needless to say that inflation meant a dreadful tax upon the toiling60 masses. As for the advantages to socialism achieved with its help, they are more than dubious61. Industry, to be sure, continued its rapid growth, but the economic efficiency of the grandiose62 construction was estimated statistically63 and not economically. Taking command of the ruble – giving it, that is, various arbitrary purchasing powers in different strata64 of the population and sectors65 of the economy – the bureaucracy deprived itself of the necessary instrument for objectively measuring its own successes and failures. The absence of correct accounting66, disguised on paper by means of combinations with the “conventional ruble”, led in reality to a decline of personal interest, to a low productivity, and to a still lower quality of goods.
In the course of the first five-year plan, this evil assumed threatening proportions. In July 1931, Stalin came out with his famous “six conditions”, whose chief aim was to lower the production cost of industrial goods. These “conditions” (payment according to individual productivity of labor, production-cost accounting, etc.) contained nothing new. The “norms of bourgeois right” had been advanced at the dawn of the NEP, and developed at the 12th Congress of the party at the beginning of 1923. Stalin happened upon them only in 1931, under the influence of the declining efficiency of capital investments. During the following two years hardly an article appeared in the Soviet press without references to the salvation67 power of these “conditions.” Meanwhile, with inflation continuing, the diseases caused by it were naturally not getting cured. Severe measures of repression69 against wreckers and sabotagers did as little to help things forward.
The fact seems almost unbelievable now that in opening a struggle against “impersonality” and “equalization” – which means anonymous71 “average” labor and similar “average” pay for all – the bureaucracy was at the same time sending “to the devil” the NEP, which means the money evaluation48 of all goods, including labor power. Restoring “bourgeois norms” with one hand, they were destroying with the other the sole implement72 of any use under them. With the substitution of “closed distributors” for commerce, and with complete chaos73 in prices, all correspondence between individual labor and individual wages necessarily disappeared, and therewith disappeared the personal interestedness of the worker.
The strictest instructions in regard to economic accounting, quality, cost of production and productivity, were left hanging in the air. This did not prevent the leaders from declaring the cause of all economic difficulties to be the malicious74 unfulfillment of the six prescriptions75 of Stalin. The most cautious references to inflation they likened to a state crime. With similar conscientiousness76 the authorities on occassion have accused teachers of breaking the rules of school hygiene77 while at the same time forbidding them to mention the absence of soap.
The question of the fate of the chervonetz has occupied a prominent place in the struggle of factions78 in the Communist party. The platform of factions in the Communist party. The platform of the Opposition79 (1927) demanded “a guarantee of the unconditional80 stability of the money unit.” This demand became a leitmotif during the subsequent years. “Stop the process of inflation with an iron hand,” wrote the émigré organ of the Opposition in 1932, “and restore a stable unit of currency,” even at the price of “a bold cutting down of capital investments.” The defenders81 of the “tortoise tempo” and the superindustrializers had, it seemed, temporarily changed places. In answer to the boast that they would send the market “to the devil”, the Opposition recommended that the State Planning Commission hang up the motto: “Inflation is the syphilis of a planned economy.”
In the sphere of agriculture, inflation brought no less heavy consequences.
During the period when the peasant policy was still oriented upon the well-to-do farmer, it was assumed that the socialist transformation82 in agriculture, setting out upon the basis of the NEP, would be accomplished83 in the course of decades by means of the co-operatives. Assuming one after another purchasing, selling, and credit functions, the co-operatives should in the long run also socialize production itself. All this taken together was called “the co-operative plan of Lenin.” The actual development, as we know, followed a completely different and almost an opposite course – dekulakization by violence and integral collectivization. Of the gradual socialization of separate economic functions, in step with the preparation of the material and cultural conditions for it, nothing more was said. Collectivization was introduced as though it were the instantaneous realization84 of the communist regime in agriculture.
The immediate85 consequence was not only an extermination86 of more than half of the livestock87, but, more important, a complete indifference88 of the members of the collective farms to the socialized property and the results of their own labor. The government was compelled to make a disorderly retreat. They again supplied the peasants with chickens, pigs, sheep, and cows as personal property. They gave them private lots adjoining the farmsteads. The film of collectivization began to be run off backwards89.
In thus restoring small personal farm holdings, the state adopted a compromise, trying to buy off, as it were, the individualistic tendencies of the peasant. The collective farms were retained, and at first glance, therefore, the retreat might seem of secondary importance. In reality, its significance could hardly be overestimated90. If you leave aside the collective farm aristocracy, the daily needs of the average peasant are still met to a greater degree by his work “on his own”, than by his participation in the collective. A peasant’s income from individual enterprises, especially when he takes up technical culture, fruit, or stock farming, amounts frequently to three times as much as the earnings91 of the same peasant in the collective economy. This fact, testified to in the Soviet press itself, very clearly reveals on the one hand a completely barbarous squandering92 of tens of million of human forces, especially those of women, in midget enterprises, and, on the other, the still extremely low productivity of labor in the collective farms.
In order to raise the standard of large-scale collective agriculture, it was necessary again to talk to the peasant in the language he understands – that is, to resurrect the markets and return from taxes in kind to trade – in a word, to ask back from Satan the NEP which had been prematurely93 sent to him. The transition to a more or less stable money accounting thus became a necessary condition for the further development of agriculture.
3. The Rehabilitation94 of the Ruble
The owl95 of wisdom flies, as is well known, after sunset. Thus the theory of a “socialist” system of money and prices was developed only after the twilight96 of inflationist illusions. In developing the above enigmatical words of Stalin, the obedient professors managed to create an entire theory according to which the Soviet price, in contrast to the market price, has an exclusively planning or directive character. That is, it is not an economic, but an administrative category, and thus serves the better for the redistribution of the people’s income in the interests of socialism. The professors forgot to explain how you can estimate real costs if all prices express the will of a bureaucracy and not the amount of socially necessary labor expended. In reality, for the redistribution of the people’s income the government has in its hands such mighty97 levers as taxes, the state budget of expenditures98 for 1936, over 37.6 billion rubles are allotted99 directly, and many billions indirectly100, to financing the various branches of economy. The budget and credit mechanism101 is wholly adequate for a planned distribution of the national income. And as to prices, they will serve the cause of socialism better, the more honestly they being to express the real economic relations of the present day.
Experience has managed to say its decisive word on this subject. “Directive” prices were less impressive in real life than in the books of scholars. On one and the same commodity, prices of different categories were established. In the broad cracks between these categories, all kinds of speculation102, favoritism, parasitism103, and other vices32 found room, and this rather as the rule than the exception. At the same time, the chervonetz, which ought to have been the steady shadow of stable prices, became in reality nothing but its own shadow.
It was again necessary to make a sharp change of course – this time as a result of difficulties which grew out of the economic successes. Nineteen-thirty-five opened with the abolition of bread cards. By October, cards for other food products were liquidated. By January 1936, cards for industrial products of general consumption were abolished. The economic relations of the city and the country to the state, and to each other, were translated into the language of money. The ruble is an instrument for the influence of the population upon economic plans, beginning with the quantity and quality of the objects of consumption. In no other manner is it possible to rationalize the Soviet economy.
The president of the State Planning Commission announced in December 1935:
“The present system of mutual104 relations between the banks and industry must be revised, and the banks must seriously realize control by the ruble.”
Thus the superstition105 of administrative plan and the illusion of administrative prices were shipwrecked. If the approach to socialism means in the fiscal106 sphere the approach of the ruble to a distribution card, then the reforms of 1935 would have to be regarded as a departure from socialism. In reality, however, such an appraisal107 would be a crude mistake. The replacement of the card by the ruble is merely a rejection108 of fictions, and an open acknowledgment of the necessity of creating the premises109 for socialism by means of a return to bourgeois methods of distribution.
At a session of the Central Executive Committee in January 1936, the People’s Commissar of Finance announced: “The Soviet ruble is stable as is not other valuta in the world.” It would be wrong to read this announcement as sheer boasting. The state budget of the Soviet union is balanced with a yearly increase of income over expenses. Foreign trade, to be sure, although insignificant110 in itself, gives an active balance. The gold reserve of the State Bank, which amount in 1926 to 164 million rubles, in now more than a billion. The output of gold in the country is rising rapidly. In 1936, this branch of industry is calculated to take first place in the world. The growth of commodity circulation under the restored market has become very rapid. Paper-money inflation was actually stopped in 1934. The elements of a certain stabilization111 of the ruble exist. Nevertheless, the announcement of the People’s Commissar of Finance must be explained to a considerable extent by an inflation of optimism. If the Soviet ruble possesses a mighty support in the general rise of industry, still its Achilles heel is the intolerably high cost of production. The ruble will become the most stable valuta only from that moment when the Soviet productivity of labor exceeds that of the rest of the world, and when, consequently, the ruble itself will be mediating112 on its final hour.
From a technically113 fiscal point of view, the ruble can still less lay claim to superiority. With a gold reserve of over a billion, about 8 billions of of bank notes are in circulation in the country. The coverage114, therefore, amounts to only 12.5 per cent. The gold in the State Bank is still considerably115 more in the nature of an inviolate116 reserve for the purposes of war, than the basis of a currency. Theoretically, to be sure, it is not impossible that at a higher stage of development the Soviets117 will resort to a gold currency, in order to make domestic economic plans precise and simplify economic relations with foreign countries. Thus, before giving up the ghost, the currency might once more flare118 up with the gleam of pure gold. But this in any case is not a problem of the immediate future.
In the period to come, there can be no talk of going over to the gold standard. Insofar, however, as the government, by increasing the gold reserve, is trying to raise the percentage even of a purely119 theoretical coverage; insofar as the limits of banknote emission120 are objectively determined121 and not dependent upon the will of the bureaucracy, to that extent the Soviet ruble may achieve at least a relative stability. That alone would be of enormous benefit. With a firm rejection of inflation in the future, the currency, although deprived of the advantage of the gold standard, could indubitably help to cure the many deep wounds inflicted122 upon the economy by the bureaucratic subjectivism of the preceding years.
4.The Stakhanov Movement
“All economy,” said Marx, – and that means all human struggle with nature at all stages of civilization – “comes down in the last analysis to an economy of time.” Reduced to its primary basis, history is nothing but a struggle for an economy of working time. Socialism could not be justified123 by the abolition of exploitation alone; it must guarantee to society a higher economy of time than is guaranteed by capitalism. Without the realization of this condition, the mere removal of exploitation would be but a dramatic episode without a future. The first historical experiment in the application of socialist methods has revealed the great possibilities contained in them. But the Soviet economy is still far from learning to make use of time, that most precious raw material of culture. The imported technique, the chief implement for the economy of time, still fails to produce on the Soviet soil those results which are normal in its capitalist fatherlands. In that sense, decisive for all civilization, socialism has not yet triumphed. It has shown that it can and should triumph. But it has not yet triumphed. All assertions to the contrary are the fruit of ignorance and charlatanism124.
Molotov, who sometimes – to do him justice – reveals a little more freedom from the ritual phrase than other Soviet leaders, declared in January 1936 at a session of the Central Executive Committee:
“Our average level of productivity of labor . . . is still considerably below that of America and Europe.”
It would be well to make these words precise approximately thus: three, five, and sometimes even 10 times as low as that of Europe and America, and our cost of production is correspondingly considerably higher. In the same speech, Molotov made a more general confession125:
“The average level of culture of our workers still stands below the corresponding level of the workers of a number of capitalist countries.”
To this should be added: also the average standard of living. There is no need of explaining how mercilessly these sober words, spoken in passing, refute the boastful announcements of the innumerable official authorities, and the honeyed outpourings of the foreign “friends”!
The struggle to raise the productivity of labor, together with concern about defense126, is the fundamental content of the activity of the Soviet government. At various stages in the evolution of the union this struggle has assumed various characters. The methods applied127 during the years of the first five-year plan and the beginning of the second, the methods of “shock brigade-ism” were based upon agricultural, personal example, administrative pressure and all kinds of group encouragements and privileges. The attempt to introduce a kind of piecework payment, on the basis of the “six conditions” of 1931, came to grief against the spectral128 character of the valuta and the heterogeneity129 of prices. The system of state distribution of products had replaced the flexible differential valuation of labor with a so-called “premium system” which meant, in essence, bureaucratic caprice. In the strife130 for copious131 privileges, there appeared in the ranks of shock brigades an increasing number of chiselers with special pull. In the long run, the whole system came into complete opposition with its own aims.
Only the abolition of the card system, the beginning of stabilization and the unification of prices, created the condition for the application of piecework payment. Upon this basis, shock brigade-ism was replaced with the so-called Stakhanov movement. In the chase after the ruble, which had now acquired a very real meaning, the workers began to concern themselves more about their machines, and make a more careful use of their working time. The Stakhanov movement to a degree comes down to an intensification132 of labor, and even to a lengthening133 of the working day. During the so-called “non-working” time, the Stakhanovists put their benches and tools in order and sort their raw material, the brigadiers instruct their brigades, etc. Of the seven-hour working day there thus remains134 nothing but the name.
It was not the Soviet administrators135 who invented the secret of piecework payment. That system, which strains the nerves without visible external compulsion, Marx considered “the most suitable to capitalistic methods of production.” The workers greeted this innovation not only without sympathy, but with hostility136. It would have been unnatural137 to expect anything else of them. The participation in the Stakhanov movement of the genuine enthusiasts138 of socialism is indubitable. To what extent they exceed the number of mere careerists and cheaters, especially in the sphere of administration, it would be hard to say. But the main mass of the workers approaches the new mode of payment from the point of view of the ruble, and is often compelled to perceive that it is getting shorter.
Although at first glance the return of the Soviet government, after “the final and irrevocable triumph of socialism”, to piecework payment might seem a retreat to capitalist relations, in reality it is necessary to repeat here what was said about the rehabilitation of the ruble: It is not a question of renouncing139 socialism, but merely of abandoning crude illusions. The form of wage payment is simply brought into better correspondence with the real resources of the country. “Law can never be higher than the economic structure.”
However, the ruling stratum140 of the Soviet union cannot yet get along without a social disguise. In a report to the Central Executive Committee in January 1936, the president of the State Planning Commission, Mezhlauk, said:
“The ruble is becoming the sole real means for the realization of a socialist (!) principle of payment for labor.”
Although in the old monarchy141 everything, even down to the public pissiors, was called royal, this does not mean that in a workers’ state everything automatically becomes socialist. The ruble is the “sole real means” for the realization of a capitalist principle of payment for labor, even though on a basis of socialist forms of property. This contradiction is already familiar to us. In instituting the new myth of a “socialist” piecework payment, Mezhlauk added:
“The fundamental principle of socialism is that each one works according to his abilities and receives payment according to the labor performed by him.”
Those gentlemen are certainly not diffident in manipulating theories! When the rhythm of labor is determined by the chase after the ruble, then people do not expend29 themselves “according to ability” – that is, according to the condition of their nerves and muscles – but in violation142 of themselves. This method can only be justified conditionally143 and by reference to stern necessity. To declare it “the fundamental principle of socialism” means cynically144 to trample the idea of a new and higher culture in the familiar filth145 of capitalism.
Stalin has taken one more step upon this road, presenting the Stakhanov movement as a “preparation of the conditions for the transition from socialism to communism.” The reader will see now how important it may be to give a scientific definition to those notions which are employed in the Soviet union according to administrative convenience. Socialism, or the lowest stage of communism, demands, to be sure, a strict control of the amount of labor and the amount of consumption, but it assumes in any case more humane146 forms of control than those invented by the exploitive genius of capital. In the Soviet union, however, there is now taking place a ruthlessly sever68 fitting in of backward human material to the technique borrowed from capitalism. In the struggle to achieve European and American standards, the classic methods of exploitation, such as piecework payment, are applied in such naked and crude forms as would not be permitted even by reformist trade unions in bourgeois countries. The consideration that in the Soviet union the workers work “for themselves” is true only in historical perspective, and only on condition – we will anticipate ourselves to say – that the workers do not submit to the saddle of an autocratic bureaucracy. In any case, state ownership of the means of production does not turn manure147 into gold, and does not surround with a halo of sanctity the sweatshop system, which wears out the greatest of all productive forces: man. As to the preparation of a “transition from socialism to communism” that will begin at the exactly opposite end – not with the introduction of piecework payment, but with its abolition as a relic148 of barbarism.
It is still early to cast the balance of the Stakhanov movement, but it is already possible to distinguish certain traits characteristic not only of the movement, but of the regime as a whole. Certain achievements of individual workers are undoubtedly149 extremely interesting as evidence of the possibilities open only to socialism. However, from these possibilities to their realization on the scale of the whole economy, is a long road. With the close dependence150 of one productive process upon another, a continual high output cannot be the result of mere personal efforts. The elevation151 of the average productivity cannot be achieved without a reorganization of production both in the separate factory and in the relations between enterprises. Moreover, to raise millions to a small degree of technical skill is immeasurably harder than to spur on a few thousand champions.
The leaders themselves, as we have heard, complain at times that the Soviet workers lack skill. However, that is only half of the truth, and the smaller half. The Russian worker is enterprising, ingenious, and gifted. Any hundred Soviet workers transferred into the conditions, let us say, of American industry, after a few months, and even weeks, would probably not fall behind the American workers of a corresponding category. The difficulty lies in the general organization of labor. The Soviet administrative personnel is, as a general rule, far less equal to the new productive tasks than the worker.
With a new technique, piecework payment should inevitably lead to a systematic152 raising of the now very low productivity of labor. But the creation of the necessary elementary conditions for this demands a raising of the level of administration itself, from the shop foreman to the leaders in the Kremlin. The Stakhanov movement only in a very small degree meets this demand. The bureaucracy tries fatally to leap over difficulties which it cannot surmount153. Since piecework payment of itself does not give the immediate miracles expected of it, a furious administrative pressure rushes to its help, with premiums154 and ballyhoos on the one side, and penalties on the other.
The first steps of the movement were signalized with mass repressions155 against the technical engineering personnel and the workers accused of resistance, sabotage70 and, in some cases, even of the murder of Stakhanovists. The severity of repressions testifies to the strength of the resistance. The bosses explained this so-called “sabotage” as a political opposition. In reality, it was most often rooted in technical, economic, and cultural difficulties, a considerable portion of which found their source in the bureaucracy itself. The “sabotage” was soon apparently156 broken. The discontented were frightened; the perspicuous were silenced. Telegrams flew around about unheard-of achievements. And in reality so long as it was a question of individual pioneers, the local administrations, obedient to orders, arranged their work with extraordinary forethought, although at the expense of the other workers in the mine or guild157. But when hundreds and thousands of workers are suddenly numbered among “Stakhanovists”, the administration gets into utter confusion. Not knowing how, and not being objectively able, to put the regime of production in order in a short space of time, it tries to violate both labor power and technique. When the clockworks slow down, it pokes158 the little wheels with a nail. As a result of the “Stakhanovist” days and ten-day periods, complete chaos was introduced into many enterprises. This explains the fact, at first glance astonishing, that a growth in the number of Stakhanovists is frequently accompanied, not with an increase, but a decrease of the general productivity of the enterprise.
At present, the “heroic” period of the movement is apparently past. The everyday grind begins. It is necessary to learn. Those especially have much to learn who teach others. But they are just the ones who least of all wish to learn. The name of that social guild which holds back and paralyzes all the guilds159 of the Soviet economy is – the bureaucracy.
点击收听单词发音
1 labor | |
n.劳动,努力,工作,劳工;分娩;vi.劳动,努力,苦干;vt.详细分析;麻烦 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
2 Soviet | |
adj.苏联的,苏维埃的;n.苏维埃 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
3 incapable | |
adj.无能力的,不能做某事的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
4 secular | |
n.牧师,凡人;adj.世俗的,现世的,不朽的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
5 lucid | |
adj.明白易懂的,清晰的,头脑清楚的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
6 worthy | |
adj.(of)值得的,配得上的;有价值的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
7 anarchist | |
n.无政府主义者 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
8 abolition | |
n.废除,取消 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
9 liquidation | |
n.清算,停止营业 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
10 mere | |
adj.纯粹的;仅仅,只不过 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
11 liquidated | |
v.清算( liquidate的过去式和过去分词 );清除(某人);清偿;变卖 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
12 ration | |
n.定量(pl.)给养,口粮;vt.定量供应 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
13 trample | |
vt.踩,践踏;无视,伤害,侵犯 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
14 entirely | |
ad.全部地,完整地;完全地,彻底地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
15 posterity | |
n.后裔,子孙,后代 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
16 conversion | |
n.转化,转换,转变 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
17 creditor | |
n.债仅人,债主,贷方 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
18 industrialist | |
n.工业家,实业家 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
19 capitalism | |
n.资本主义 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
20 administrative | |
adj.行政的,管理的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
21 sufficiently | |
adv.足够地,充分地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
22 fixed | |
adj.固定的,不变的,准备好的;(计算机)固定的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
23 accurately | |
adv.准确地,精确地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
24 participation | |
n.参与,参加,分享 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
25 epoch | |
n.(新)时代;历元 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
26 quantitatively | |
adv.数量上 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
27 qualitatively | |
质量上 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
28 formerly | |
adv.从前,以前 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
29 expend | |
vt.花费,消费,消耗 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
30 expended | |
v.花费( expend的过去式和过去分词 );使用(钱等)做某事;用光;耗尽 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
31 dwelling | |
n.住宅,住所,寓所 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
32 vices | |
缺陷( vice的名词复数 ); 恶习; 不道德行为; 台钳 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
33 socialist | |
n.社会主义者;adj.社会主义的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
34 penetrating | |
adj.(声音)响亮的,尖锐的adj.(气味)刺激的adj.(思想)敏锐的,有洞察力的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
35 authentic | |
a.真的,真正的;可靠的,可信的,有根据的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
36 machinery | |
n.(总称)机械,机器;机构 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
37 adverse | |
adj.不利的;有害的;敌对的,不友好的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
38 possessed | |
adj.疯狂的;拥有的,占有的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
39 virtue | |
n.德行,美德;贞操;优点;功效,效力 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
40 zigzags | |
n.锯齿形的线条、小径等( zigzag的名词复数 )v.弯弯曲曲地走路,曲折地前进( zigzag的第三人称单数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
41 bureaucratic | |
adj.官僚的,繁文缛节的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
42 bourgeois | |
adj./n.追求物质享受的(人);中产阶级分子 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
43 sluices | |
n.水闸( sluice的名词复数 );(用水闸控制的)水;有闸人工水道;漂洗处v.冲洗( sluice的第三人称单数 );(指水)喷涌而出;漂净;给…安装水闸 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
44 metallic | |
adj.金属的;金属制的;含金属的;产金属的;像金属的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
45 depicted | |
描绘,描画( depict的过去式和过去分词 ); 描述 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
46 feverish | |
adj.发烧的,狂热的,兴奋的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
47 conditional | |
adj.条件的,带有条件的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
48 evaluation | |
n.估价,评价;赋值 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
49 replacement | |
n.取代,替换,交换;替代品,代用品 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
50 aphorism | |
n.格言,警语 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
51 elucidation | |
n.说明,阐明 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
52 lengthen | |
vt.使伸长,延长 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
53 doctrine | |
n.教义;主义;学说 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
54 alas | |
int.唉(表示悲伤、忧愁、恐惧等) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
55 inadequate | |
adj.(for,to)不充足的,不适当的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
56 inevitably | |
adv.不可避免地;必然发生地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
57 entails | |
使…成为必要( entail的第三人称单数 ); 需要; 限定继承; 使必需 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
58 fictitious | |
adj.虚构的,假设的;空头的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
59 corrodes | |
v.使腐蚀,侵蚀( corrode的第三人称单数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
60 toiling | |
长时间或辛苦地工作( toil的现在分词 ); 艰难缓慢地移动,跋涉 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
61 dubious | |
adj.怀疑的,无把握的;有问题的,靠不住的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
62 grandiose | |
adj.宏伟的,宏大的,堂皇的,铺张的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
63 statistically | |
ad.根据统计数据来看,从统计学的观点来看 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
64 strata | |
n.地层(复数);社会阶层 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
65 sectors | |
n.部门( sector的名词复数 );领域;防御地区;扇形 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
66 accounting | |
n.会计,会计学,借贷对照表 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
67 salvation | |
n.(尤指基督)救世,超度,拯救,解困 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
68 sever | |
v.切开,割开;断绝,中断 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
69 repression | |
n.镇压,抑制,抑压 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
70 sabotage | |
n.怠工,破坏活动,破坏;v.从事破坏活动,妨害,破坏 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
71 anonymous | |
adj.无名的;匿名的;无特色的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
72 implement | |
n.(pl.)工具,器具;vt.实行,实施,执行 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
73 chaos | |
n.混乱,无秩序 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
74 malicious | |
adj.有恶意的,心怀恶意的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
75 prescriptions | |
药( prescription的名词复数 ); 处方; 开处方; 计划 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
76 conscientiousness | |
责任心 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
77 hygiene | |
n.健康法,卫生学 (a.hygienic) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
78 factions | |
组织中的小派别,派系( faction的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
79 opposition | |
n.反对,敌对 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
80 unconditional | |
adj.无条件的,无限制的,绝对的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
81 defenders | |
n.防御者( defender的名词复数 );守卫者;保护者;辩护者 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
82 transformation | |
n.变化;改造;转变 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
83 accomplished | |
adj.有才艺的;有造诣的;达到了的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
84 realization | |
n.实现;认识到,深刻了解 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
85 immediate | |
adj.立即的;直接的,最接近的;紧靠的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
86 extermination | |
n.消灭,根绝 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
87 livestock | |
n.家畜,牲畜 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
88 indifference | |
n.不感兴趣,不关心,冷淡,不在乎 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
89 backwards | |
adv.往回地,向原处,倒,相反,前后倒置地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
90 overestimated | |
对(数量)估计过高,对…作过高的评价( overestimate的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
91 earnings | |
n.工资收人;利润,利益,所得 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
92 squandering | |
v.(指钱,财产等)浪费,乱花( squander的现在分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
93 prematurely | |
adv.过早地,贸然地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
94 rehabilitation | |
n.康复,悔过自新,修复,复兴,复职,复位 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
95 owl | |
n.猫头鹰,枭 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
96 twilight | |
n.暮光,黄昏;暮年,晚期,衰落时期 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
97 mighty | |
adj.强有力的;巨大的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
98 expenditures | |
n.花费( expenditure的名词复数 );使用;(尤指金钱的)支出额;(精力、时间、材料等的)耗费 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
99 allotted | |
分配,拨给,摊派( allot的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
100 indirectly | |
adv.间接地,不直接了当地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
101 mechanism | |
n.机械装置;机构,结构 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
102 speculation | |
n.思索,沉思;猜测;投机 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
103 parasitism | |
n.寄生状态,寄生病;寄生性 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
104 mutual | |
adj.相互的,彼此的;共同的,共有的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
105 superstition | |
n.迷信,迷信行为 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
106 fiscal | |
adj.财政的,会计的,国库的,国库岁入的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
107 appraisal | |
n.对…作出的评价;评价,鉴定,评估 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
108 rejection | |
n.拒绝,被拒,抛弃,被弃 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
109 premises | |
n.建筑物,房屋 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
110 insignificant | |
adj.无关紧要的,可忽略的,无意义的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
111 Stabilization | |
稳定化 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
112 mediating | |
调停,调解,斡旋( mediate的现在分词 ); 居间促成; 影响…的发生; 使…可能发生 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
113 technically | |
adv.专门地,技术上地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
114 coverage | |
n.报导,保险范围,保险额,范围,覆盖 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
115 considerably | |
adv.极大地;相当大地;在很大程度上 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
116 inviolate | |
adj.未亵渎的,未受侵犯的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
117 soviets | |
苏维埃(Soviet的复数形式) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
118 flare | |
v.闪耀,闪烁;n.潮红;突发 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
119 purely | |
adv.纯粹地,完全地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
120 emission | |
n.发出物,散发物;发出,散发 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
121 determined | |
adj.坚定的;有决心的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
122 inflicted | |
把…强加给,使承受,遭受( inflict的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
123 justified | |
a.正当的,有理的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
124 charlatanism | |
n.庸医术,庸医的行为 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
125 confession | |
n.自白,供认,承认 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
126 defense | |
n.防御,保卫;[pl.]防务工事;辩护,答辩 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
127 applied | |
adj.应用的;v.应用,适用 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
128 spectral | |
adj.幽灵的,鬼魂的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
129 heterogeneity | |
n.异质性;多相性 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
130 strife | |
n.争吵,冲突,倾轧,竞争 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
131 copious | |
adj.丰富的,大量的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
132 intensification | |
n.激烈化,增强明暗度;加厚 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
133 lengthening | |
(时间或空间)延长,伸长( lengthen的现在分词 ); 加长 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
134 remains | |
n.剩余物,残留物;遗体,遗迹 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
135 administrators | |
n.管理者( administrator的名词复数 );有管理(或行政)才能的人;(由遗嘱检验法庭指定的)遗产管理人;奉派暂管主教教区的牧师 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
136 hostility | |
n.敌对,敌意;抵制[pl.]交战,战争 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
137 unnatural | |
adj.不自然的;反常的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
138 enthusiasts | |
n.热心人,热衷者( enthusiast的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
139 renouncing | |
v.声明放弃( renounce的现在分词 );宣布放弃;宣布与…决裂;宣布摒弃 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
140 stratum | |
n.地层,社会阶层 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
141 monarchy | |
n.君主,最高统治者;君主政体,君主国 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
142 violation | |
n.违反(行为),违背(行为),侵犯 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
143 conditionally | |
adv. 有条件地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
144 cynically | |
adv.爱嘲笑地,冷笑地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
145 filth | |
n.肮脏,污物,污秽;淫猥 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
146 humane | |
adj.人道的,富有同情心的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
147 manure | |
n.粪,肥,肥粒;vt.施肥 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
148 relic | |
n.神圣的遗物,遗迹,纪念物 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
149 undoubtedly | |
adv.确实地,无疑地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
150 dependence | |
n.依靠,依赖;信任,信赖;隶属 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
151 elevation | |
n.高度;海拔;高地;上升;提高 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
152 systematic | |
adj.有系统的,有计划的,有方法的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
153 surmount | |
vt.克服;置于…顶上 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
154 premiums | |
n.费用( premium的名词复数 );保险费;额外费用;(商品定价、贷款利息等以外的)加价 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
155 repressions | |
n.压抑( repression的名词复数 );约束;抑制;镇压 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
156 apparently | |
adv.显然地;表面上,似乎 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
157 guild | |
n.行会,同业公会,协会 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
158 pokes | |
v.伸出( poke的第三人称单数 );戳出;拨弄;与(某人)性交 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
159 guilds | |
行会,同业公会,协会( guild的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
欢迎访问英文小说网 |