What has been said of servants and masters is applicable, to a certain extent, to landowners and farming tenants1; but this subject deserves to be considered by itself. In America there are, properly speaking, no tenant2 farmers; every man owns the ground he tills. It must be admitted that democratic laws tend greatly to increase the number of landowners, and to diminish that of farming tenants. Yet what takes place in the United States is much less attributable to the institutions of the country than to the country itself. In America land is cheap, and anyone may easily become a landowner; its returns are small, and its produce cannot well be divided between a landowner and a farmer. America therefore stands alone in this as well as in many other respects, and it would be a mistake to take it as an example.
I believe that in democratic as well as in aristocratic countries there will be landowners and tenants, but the connection existing between them will be of a different kind. In aristocracies the hire of a farm is paid to the landlord, not only in rent, but in respect, regard, and duty; in democracies the whole is paid in cash. When estates are divided and passed from hand to hand, and the permanent connection which existed between families and the soil is dissolved, the landowner and the tenant are only casually3 brought into contact. They meet for a moment to settle the conditions of the agreement, and then lose sight of each other; they are two strangers brought together by a common interest, and who keenly talk over a matter of business, the sole object of which is to make money.
In proportion as property is subdivided4 and wealth distributed over the country, the community is filled with people whose former opulence5 is declining, and with others whose fortunes are of recent growth and whose wants increase more rapidly than their resources. For all such persons the smallest pecuniary6 profit is a matter of importance, and none of them feel disposed to waive7 any of their claims, or to lose any portion of their income. As ranks are intermingled, and as very large as well as very scanty8 fortunes become more rare, every day brings the social condition of the landowner nearer to that of the farmer; the one has not naturally any uncontested superiority over the other; between two men who are equal, and not at ease in their circumstances, the contract of hire is exclusively an affair of money. A man whose estate extends over a whole district, and who owns a hundred farms, is well aware of the importance of gaining at the same time the affections of some thousands of men; this object appears to call for his exertions9, and to attain10 it he will readily make considerable sacrifices. But he who owns a hundred acres is insensible to similar considerations, and he cares but little to win the private regard of his tenant.
An aristocracy does not expire like a man in a single day; the aristocratic principle is slowly undermined in men's opinion, before it is attacked in their laws. Long before open war is declared against it, the tie which had hitherto united the higher classes to the lower may be seen to be gradually relaxed. Indifference11 and contempt are betrayed by one class, jealousy12 and hatred13 by the others; the intercourse14 between rich and poor becomes less frequent and less kind, and rents are raised. This is not the consequence of a democratic revolution, but its certain harbinger; for an aristocracy which has lost the affections of the people, once and forever, is like a tree dead at the root, which is the more easily torn up by the winds the higher its branches have spread.
In the course of the last fifty years the rents of farms have amazingly increased, not only in France but throughout the greater part of Europe. The remarkable15 improvements which have taken place in agriculture and manufactures within the same period do not suffice in my opinion to explain this fact; recourse must be had to another cause more powerful and more concealed16. I believe that cause is to be found in the democratic institutions which several European nations have adopted, and in the democratic passions which more or less agitate17 all the rest. I have frequently heard great English landowners congratulate themselves that, at the present day, they derive18 a much larger income from their estates than their fathers did. They have perhaps good reasons to be glad; but most assuredly they know not what they are glad of. They think they are making a clear gain, when it is in reality only an exchange; their influence is what they are parting with for cash; and what they gain in money will ere long be lost in power.
There is yet another sign by which it is easy to know that a great democratic revolution is going on or approaching. In the Middle Ages almost all lands were leased for lives, or for very long terms; the domestic economy of that period shows that leases for ninety-nine years were more frequent then than leases for twelve years are now. Men then believed that families were immortal19; men's conditions seemed settled forever, and the whole of society appeared to be so fixed20, that it was not supposed that anything would ever be stirred or shaken in its structure. In ages of equality, the human mind takes a different bent21; the prevailing22 notion is that nothing abides23, and man is haunted by the thought of mutability. Under this impression the landowner and the tenant himself are instinctively24 averse25 to protracted26 terms of obligation; they are afraid of being tied up to-morrow by the contract which benefits them today. They have vague anticipations27 of some sudden and unforeseen change in their conditions; they mistrust themselves; they fear lest their taste should change, and lest they should lament28 that they cannot rid themselves of what they coveted29; nor are such fears unfounded, for in democratic ages that which is most fluctuating amidst the fluctuation30 of all around is the heart of man.
点击收听单词发音
1 tenants | |
n.房客( tenant的名词复数 );佃户;占用者;占有者 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
2 tenant | |
n.承租人;房客;佃户;v.租借,租用 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
3 casually | |
adv.漠不关心地,无动于衷地,不负责任地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
4 subdivided | |
再分,细分( subdivide的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
5 opulence | |
n.财富,富裕 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
6 pecuniary | |
adj.金钱的;金钱上的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
7 waive | |
vt.放弃,不坚持(规定、要求、权力等) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
8 scanty | |
adj.缺乏的,仅有的,节省的,狭小的,不够的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
9 exertions | |
n.努力( exertion的名词复数 );费力;(能力、权力等的)运用;行使 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
10 attain | |
vt.达到,获得,完成 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
11 indifference | |
n.不感兴趣,不关心,冷淡,不在乎 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
12 jealousy | |
n.妒忌,嫉妒,猜忌 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
13 hatred | |
n.憎恶,憎恨,仇恨 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
14 intercourse | |
n.性交;交流,交往,交际 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
15 remarkable | |
adj.显著的,异常的,非凡的,值得注意的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
16 concealed | |
a.隐藏的,隐蔽的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
17 agitate | |
vi.(for,against)煽动,鼓动;vt.搅动 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
18 derive | |
v.取得;导出;引申;来自;源自;出自 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
19 immortal | |
adj.不朽的;永生的,不死的;神的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
20 fixed | |
adj.固定的,不变的,准备好的;(计算机)固定的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
21 bent | |
n.爱好,癖好;adj.弯的;决心的,一心的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
22 prevailing | |
adj.盛行的;占优势的;主要的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
23 abides | |
容忍( abide的第三人称单数 ); 等候; 逗留; 停留 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
24 instinctively | |
adv.本能地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
25 averse | |
adj.厌恶的;反对的,不乐意的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
26 protracted | |
adj.拖延的;延长的v.拖延“protract”的过去式和过去分词 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
27 anticipations | |
预期( anticipation的名词复数 ); 预测; (信托财产收益的)预支; 预期的事物 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
28 lament | |
n.悲叹,悔恨,恸哭;v.哀悼,悔恨,悲叹 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
29 coveted | |
adj.令人垂涎的;垂涎的,梦寐以求的v.贪求,觊觎(covet的过去分词);垂涎;贪图 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
30 fluctuation | |
n.(物价的)波动,涨落;周期性变动;脉动 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
欢迎访问英文小说网 |