It was in 1862 that Lassalle began his agitation15 in behalf of the laboring17 classes, an agitation which resulted in the formation of the German Social Democratic Party. Previous to his time, German laborers18 had been considered contented20 and peaceable. It had been thought that a working-men’s party might be established in France or England, but that it was hopeless to attempt to move the phlegmatic21 German laborers. Lassalle’s historical importance lies in the fact that he was able to work upon the laborers so powerfully as to arouse them to action. It is due to Lassalle above all others that German working-men’s battalions23, to use the social democratic expression, now[191] form the vanguard in the struggle for the emancipation24 of labor16.
Lassalle’s writings did not advance materially the theory of social democracy. He drew from Rodbertus and Marx in his economic writings, but he clothed their thoughts in such manner as to enable ordinary laborers to understand them, and this they never could have done without such help. Even for an educated man their works are not easy reading; for the uneducated they are quite incomprehensible. Lassalle’s speeches and pamphlets were eloquent25 sermons on texts taken from Marx. Lassalle gave to Ricardo’s law of wages the designation, the iron law of wages, and expounded26 to the laborers its full significance, showing them how it inevitably27 forced wages down to a level just sufficient to enable them to live. He acknowledged that it was the key-stone of his system, and that his doctrines28 stood or fell with it.
Laborers were told that this law could be overthrown30 only by the abolition31 of the wages system. How Lassalle really thought this was to be accomplished32 is not so evident. He proposed to the laborers that government should aid them by the use of its credit to the extent of 100,000,000 of thalers, to establish co-operative associations for production; and a great deal of breath has been wasted to show the inadequacy33 of his proposed measures. Lassalle could not himself have supposed that so insignificant34 a matter as the granting of a small loan would solve the labor question. He recognized, however, that it was necessary to have some definite party programme to insure success in agitation, and could think of no better plan at the time than to work for universal suffrage35 and a government subsidy36. He wrote to his[192] friend Rodbertus to the effect that he was willing to drop the latter plank37 in his platform, if something better could be suggested.[182] It would be going too far to say that he was positively38 insincere, for he might have thought that if government had voted the proposed credit of one hundred millions, it would have opened the way for other reforms. He might have regarded this modest proposal merely as an entering wedge.
Lassalle took this project of productive co-operative associations founded on government loans from Louis Blanc, with whose work he was well acquainted; indeed, as he began his agitation, he wrote to the French socialist39, and requested some kind of an open letter of recognition which should give him credit with the laborers.[183] We may get some clew to thoughts possibly lingering in the background, which Lassalle might have intended to express later by recalling the proposals of the Frenchman. Louis Blanc, as will be remembered, wished government to use its power of taxation40 to assist the social workshops with large advances of money, for which no interest was to be charged. No one was to be forced to join these ateliers sociaux. According to this scheme private manufacturers are allowed to continue their business as long as they choose. However, as no interest is paid for the government loans to the co-operative[193] undertakings41, the public establishments will be in a position to undersell private employers of labor and thus compel them to fall in line. The only possible termination is the socialistic state. As Lassalle was thoroughly42 informed concerning Blanc’s ideas, it is quite possible that in the course of time he may have intended to go equally far. The way he presented the matter to the laborers was somewhat as follows: There exists at present a conflict between labor and capital, which must be abolished. This contradiction between the elements of production can only be terminated by their union in co-operative associations, in which no capitalist comes between the working-man and the fruits of his toil43, to levy44 toll45 thereon. But at the present time only large establishments can succeed, as the increased division of labor makes it necessary to employ a large force of men, and mechanical inventions have forced producers to use many and expensive machines. The laborers have not the means to found large manufactories; consequently government must advance these means in order to cause the existing and unhappy social conflict to cease. Government is to advance capital to different groups of laborers, who conduct various enterprises. These groups are associated, new ones are continually added, and, finally, their united power is so great that they can stand alone without government aid.
This all appears harmless enough, and no government would be justified46 in refusing 100,000,000 of thalers, or $75,000,000, if so much good could be done by it. But one of the ablest men of his time must have been fully22 conscious of the utter insufficiency of such a sum. If he had any other idea in his mind[194] than simply to use his demand of government as a rallying-point for purposes of agitation, it cannot well be doubted that he had further petitions to address to government as soon as they had granted his first one. It is not at all improbable he might have been willing to see collateral47 inheritances abolished, and the income derived48 therefrom devoted to co-operative undertakings. Proposals, like abolition of interest on loans, must have followed, with the view of rendering49 private competition impossible. Thus would be introduced the socialistic state longed for by the social democratic party founded by Lassalle.
“On the 23d of May, 1863, German social democracy was born. Little importance was attached to the event at the time. A few men met at Leipsic, and, under the leadership of Ferdinand Lassalle, formed a new political party called the ‘Universal German Laborers’ union’ (‘Der Allgemeine Deutsche Arbeiterverein’). That was all. Surely, no one could be expected to ascribe great weight to the fact that a handful of working-men, led by a dreamer, had met and passed a few resolutions—resolutions, too, as modest in their expression of purpose as they were harmless in appearance. It was simply declared that the laborers ought to be represented in the different German parliaments, as only thus could their interests be adequately cared for and the opposition50 between the various classes of society terminated; and in view of this fact it was resolved that the members of the union should avail themselves of all peaceful and legal means in endeavoring to bring about universal suffrage.
“But it was soon discovered that the members of the union, the first organization in Germany of social democracy, desired political power only as a means of[195] overthrowing51 entirely52 the existing order of the production and distribution of wealth.”[184]
Lassalle never tired of representing in vivid colors the injustice53 of our present social institutions. The crimes, selfishness, and heartlessness of the bourgeoisie were unfailing topics in his agitation. The laborers were told that they had no right to be contented with their lot. It is this damnable, easily satisfied disposition54 of you German laborers which is your ruin, they were told.[185]
“The German laborer19 was finally moved. His anger and discontent became permanent and terrible in proportion as it had been difficult to arouse him. He was not to be easily pacified55. He soon showed strength and determination in such manner as to attract the attention of the civilized56 world. Statesmen grew pale and kings trembled.”[186]
Lassalle did not live to see the fruits of his labors57. He met with some success and celebrated58 a few triumphs, but the union did not flourish as he hoped. At the time of his death he did not appear to have a firm, lasting59 hold on the laboring population. There then existed no social-democratic party with political power. Although Lassalle lost his life in a duel60, which had its origin in a love affair, and not in any struggle for the rights of labor, he was canonized at once by the working-men, and took his place among the greatest martyrs61 and heroes of all times. His influence increased more than tenfold as soon as he ceased to live.[196] This was not entirely undeserved. Men remembered and appreciated better his extraordinary talents and his ardent62, romantic temperament. Even Bismarck, with whom he had been personally acquainted, took occasion once, in the Reichstag, to express his admiration for Lassalle. I was in Germany at the time, and remember well what a sensation his words created. He expressed himself as follows:[187] “I met Lassalle three or four times. Our relations were not of a political nature. Politically he had nothing which he could offer me. He attracted me extraordinarily63 as a private man. Lassalle was one of the most gifted and amiable64 men with whom I have ever associated—a man who was ambitious on a grand scale, but not the least of a republican. He had a very marked inclination65 towards a national monarchy66; the idea towards the attainment67 of which his efforts were directed was the German Empire, and in this we found a point of contact. Lassalle was ambitious on a grand scale, and whether the German Empire should close with the house of Hohenzollern or the house of Lassalle, that was perhaps doubtful; but his sympathies were through and through monarchical68.... Lassalle was an energetic and exceedingly clever man, and it was always instructive to talk with him. Our conversations have lasted for hours, and I have always regretted their close.... It would have given me great pleasure to have had a similarly gifted man for a neighbor in my country home.”
It has, indeed, been stated that Lassalle, at the time of his death, had some thoughts of making terms[197] with the Prussian government. He was to come out as a supporter of Bismarck, and to receive a high appointment in return. I am unable to say how much truth there may be in this report. It is possible he may have begun to lose faith in social democracy; still it must be confessed that he was not a man to be easily diverted from a purpose which he had once formed. This is abundantly shown by his indomitable perseverance69 in the case of the Countess von Hatzfeldt. It is nevertheless significant that the second edition of his “System of Acquired Rights,” which appeared in 1881, was edited by Lothar Bucher, who bears the title of privy-councillor and holds a high position under the government in Berlin.
There are three doctrines upon which the social democratic leaders lay especial stress in their attacks on the economic institutions of to-day.
The first is “Das eherne Lohngesetz”—“The Iron Law of Wages”—or “Cruel Iron Law of Wages,” as it is also called. It is with this law that the name of Lassalle is especially connected.
The second doctrine29 teaches the systematic70 robbery of laborers by capitalists. They rob them by taking from them all the surplus value which they produce, over and above the means necessary to sustain life. This is Marx’s doctrine of the appropriation71 of surplus value (Mehrwerth) by employers.
The third doctrine is Marx’s theory of industrial crises and panics.
What is “The Iron Law of Wages”? It is, as already stated, only Lassalle’s statement and interpretation72 of Ricardo’s “Law of Wages.” Ricardo expresses his law in these words: “The natural price of labor is that price which is necessary to enable the laborers,[198] one with another, to subsist73 and to perpetuate74 their race, without either increase or diminution75.” Ricardo has previously76 explained what is to be understood by market price and what by natural price. Market price is the price actually obtained for an article; the natural price is that which pays labor and the profits of capital. Through miscalculation, too much or too little of a commodity is at times offered on the market, and it departs from its natural price. If too little is offered, profits will be too high, and capital will rush to the production of the commodity in order to gain the unusual profits, until competition forces them down to the usual rate, or, very likely, below it, when capital will be withdrawn77 from the production of said commodity. So the market price fluctuates about the natural price with a continual tendency to return to it. Now, labor is a commodity, and may be increased or diminished in quantity like other commodities. In an advancing state of society the market price will be above the natural price, and may continue so for a long time; but early and frequent marriages and large families will produce all the labor required, and reduce it to its natural price eventually. In a declining state of society, on the other hand, labor would sink below its natural price, and the supply would diminish on account of frequent deaths, few marriages, and small families.
This law of wages may be difficult for those to comprehend who are not thoroughly familiar with economic discussions. In order to make it clearer, I will quote, with a few changes and abbreviations, a passage of some length from John Stuart Mill,[188][199] giving a lucid78 explanation of the law. “Mr. Ricardo assumes,” says Mill, “that there is everywhere a minimum rate of wages—either the lowest with which it is physically79 possible to keep up the population, or the lowest with which the people will choose to do. To this minimum he assumes that the general rate of wages always tends; that they can never be lower beyond the length of time required for a diminished rate of increase to make itself felt, and can never long continue higher. This assumption contains sufficient truth to render it admissible for the purposes of abstract science.... But in the application to practice it is necessary to consider that the minimum of which he speaks, especially when it is not a physical, but what may be termed a moral minimum, is itself liable to vary.” A rise of the price of food will permanently80 lower the standard of living of laborers, “in case their previous habits in respect of population prove stronger than their previous habits in respect of comfort. In that case the injury done to them will be permanent, and their deteriorated81 condition will become a new minimum, tending to perpetuate itself as the more ample minimum did before.” It is to be feared that this is the way in which a rise in the price of provisions usually operates. “There is considerable evidence that the circumstances of the agricultural laborers in England have more than once in our history sustained great permanent deterioration82 from causes which operated by diminishing the demand for labor, and which, if population had exercised its power of self-adjustment, in obedience83 to the previous standard of comfort, could only have had a temporary effect; but, unhappily, the poverty in which the class was plunged84 during a long series of years[200] brought that previous standard into disuse, and the next generation, growing up without having possessed85 those pristine86 comforts, multiplied in turn without any attempt to retrieve87 them.” ... The salutary effect of a fall in the price of food is of no permanent value “if laborers content themselves with enjoying the greater comfort while it lasts, but do not learn to require it.... If from poverty their children had previously been insufficiently89 fed or improperly90 nursed, a greater number will now be reared, and the competition of these, when they grow up, will depress wages probably in full proportion to the greater cheapness of food. If the effect is not produced in this mode, it will be produced by earlier and more numerous marriages, or by an increased number of births to a marriage.” I believe Mill renders the law as plain as it can be made, without entering into subjects foreign to this work. The standpoint is this: labor is a commodity, like wheat or potatoes, which is increased or decreased according to the existing demand. The laborers live not for themselves, but solely91 for the higher classes, in particular, for the capitalists. This is the way Lassalle expresses it to the laborers of Frankfort in an eloquent speech, which has not yet ceased to be a power in Germany: “What is the consequence of that law, which, as I have proved to you, is accepted by all political economists92? What is the consequence of the same? I ask. You believe, perhaps, laborers and fellow-citizens, that you are human beings—that you are men. Speaking from the standpoint of political economy, you make a terrible mistake. Speaking from the standpoint of political economy, you are nothing but a commodity, a high price for which increases your numbers, just the same as a high price[201] for stockings increases the number of stockings, if there are not enough of them; and you are swept away, your number is diminished by smaller wages—by what Malthus calls the preventive and positive checks to population; your number is diminished, just as if you were vermin against which society wages war.” Lassalle then shows them how much shorter the average of life is among the laboring classes than among the wealthy. He demonstrates to them that poor and insufficient88 food means starvation. “There are, gentlemen,” says he, “two ways of dying of starvation. It, indeed, happens seldom that a man falls down dead in a moment from hunger; but when a man is subjected to a greater expenditure93 of power than he is able to replace, on account of poor food or a miserable94 mode of life—when he gives out more physical energy than he takes in—then, I say, he dies of slow starvation.”
Rehearse this in a thousand different ways and with all the resources of oratorical95 art, to laborers really ill-fed, ill-housed, and ill-clothed, and you shall indeed find yourself soon standing96 upon a volcano, whose forces are no longer latent and slumbering97.
In his definition of capital Lassalle clothes the same thought contained in his “Iron Law of Wages” in other words. The definition reads as follows: “Capital exists where a division of labor obtains and where production consists in the creation of values in exchange, and in such a system of production it is the advance of labor already performed (congealed, coagulated labor), which is necessary to sustain the life of the producer. This advance of coagulated labor brings it to pass that the excess of labor’s product over and above what is necessary to support the life of the producer[202] accrues98 to the person or persons who made the advance.”
The more one reflects upon this definition, the more meaning is discovered in it. It has furnished the text for many a social-democratic sermon. Like Marx, Lassalle holds that capital is based on a theft—on that theft, namely, “which deprived the masses of their right in the soil, in the earth—the common heritage of all.”
It is substantially the same doctrine which we have met with so often—viz., that labor alone is the source of wealth, and if capitalist and landlord could be swept out of existence the entire social product would go to the laborer. It resulted from a one-sided development of certain teachings of Adam Smith’s “Wealth of Nations.” “The produce of labor,” says Adam Smith, in one place—and, as will be seen, he means the entire product—“constitutes the natural recompense or wages of labor.
“In that original state of things which precedes both the appropriation of land and the accumulation of stock, the whole produce of labor belongs to the laborer. He has neither landlord nor master to share with him.
“Had this state continued, the wages of labor would have augmented99 with all those improvements in its productive powers to which the division of labor gives occasion. All things would gradually have become cheaper. They would have been produced by a smaller quantity of labor; and as the commodities produced by equal quantities of labor would naturally, in this state of things, be exchanged for one another, they would have been purchased likewise with the produce of a smaller quantity.”[189]
[203]
Repeat this to the man toiling100 and moiling for a bare subsistence, while he crouches101 before the employing capitalist surfeited102 in luxury; or to the poor tenant103 farmer, whose half-starved family can hardly find the wherewithal to cover their nakedness, while his absentee landlord indulges in the extravagant pleasures of a gay capital—and do you imagine that from it he will be slow to draw a very natural conclusion, and one fraught104 with tremendous practical consequences? If that originally and naturally belonged to him which another now enjoys, will he not long to return to the state of nature? As he reflects upon his wrongs and sufferings, will he not be filled with hatred105 towards that one who, as he thinks, unjustly and cruelly keeps him from the fruits of his labor? And as time goes on, and the hardships he endures sink more and more deeply into his mind, will he not finally, in desperation, resolve to put down his oppressor, be he landlord or be he capitalist, and to reverse, by the force of a strong right arm, an unnatural106 and artificial social organization?
In that thought and in that determination originated social democracy.
点击收听单词发音
1 wholesale | |
n.批发;adv.以批发方式;vt.批发,成批出售 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
2 devoted | |
adj.忠诚的,忠实的,热心的,献身于...的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
3 philology | |
n.语言学;语文学 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
4 distinguished | |
adj.卓越的,杰出的,著名的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
5 admiration | |
n.钦佩,赞美,羡慕 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
6 miraculous | |
adj.像奇迹一样的,不可思议的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
7 misused | |
v.使用…不当( misuse的过去式和过去分词 );把…派作不正当的用途;虐待;滥用 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
8 brutal | |
adj.残忍的,野蛮的,不讲理的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
9 extravagant | |
adj.奢侈的;过分的;(言行等)放肆的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
10 cramped | |
a.狭窄的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
11 motives | |
n.动机,目的( motive的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
12 redressing | |
v.改正( redress的现在分词 );重加权衡;恢复平衡 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
13 fiery | |
adj.燃烧着的,火红的;暴躁的;激烈的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
14 temperament | |
n.气质,性格,性情 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
15 agitation | |
n.搅动;搅拌;鼓动,煽动 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
16 labor | |
n.劳动,努力,工作,劳工;分娩;vi.劳动,努力,苦干;vt.详细分析;麻烦 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
17 laboring | |
n.劳动,操劳v.努力争取(for)( labor的现在分词 );苦干;详细分析;(指引擎)缓慢而困难地运转 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
18 laborers | |
n.体力劳动者,工人( laborer的名词复数 );(熟练工人的)辅助工 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
19 laborer | |
n.劳动者,劳工 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
20 contented | |
adj.满意的,安心的,知足的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
21 phlegmatic | |
adj.冷静的,冷淡的,冷漠的,无活力的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
22 fully | |
adv.完全地,全部地,彻底地;充分地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
23 battalions | |
n.(陆军的)一营(大约有一千兵士)( battalion的名词复数 );协同作战的部队;军队;(组织在一起工作的)队伍 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
24 emancipation | |
n.(从束缚、支配下)解放 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
25 eloquent | |
adj.雄辩的,口才流利的;明白显示出的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
26 expounded | |
论述,详细讲解( expound的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
27 inevitably | |
adv.不可避免地;必然发生地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
28 doctrines | |
n.教条( doctrine的名词复数 );教义;学说;(政府政策的)正式声明 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
29 doctrine | |
n.教义;主义;学说 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
30 overthrown | |
adj. 打翻的,推倒的,倾覆的 动词overthrow的过去分词 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
31 abolition | |
n.废除,取消 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
32 accomplished | |
adj.有才艺的;有造诣的;达到了的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
33 inadequacy | |
n.无法胜任,信心不足 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
34 insignificant | |
adj.无关紧要的,可忽略的,无意义的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
35 suffrage | |
n.投票,选举权,参政权 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
36 subsidy | |
n.补助金,津贴 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
37 plank | |
n.板条,木板,政策要点,政纲条目 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
38 positively | |
adv.明确地,断然,坚决地;实在,确实 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
39 socialist | |
n.社会主义者;adj.社会主义的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
40 taxation | |
n.征税,税收,税金 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
41 undertakings | |
企业( undertaking的名词复数 ); 保证; 殡仪业; 任务 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
42 thoroughly | |
adv.完全地,彻底地,十足地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
43 toil | |
vi.辛劳工作,艰难地行动;n.苦工,难事 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
44 levy | |
n.征收税或其他款项,征收额 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
45 toll | |
n.过路(桥)费;损失,伤亡人数;v.敲(钟) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
46 justified | |
a.正当的,有理的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
47 collateral | |
adj.平行的;旁系的;n.担保品 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
48 derived | |
vi.起源;由来;衍生;导出v.得到( derive的过去式和过去分词 );(从…中)得到获得;源于;(从…中)提取 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
49 rendering | |
n.表现,描写 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
50 opposition | |
n.反对,敌对 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
51 overthrowing | |
v.打倒,推翻( overthrow的现在分词 );使终止 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
52 entirely | |
ad.全部地,完整地;完全地,彻底地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
53 injustice | |
n.非正义,不公正,不公平,侵犯(别人的)权利 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
54 disposition | |
n.性情,性格;意向,倾向;排列,部署 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
55 pacified | |
使(某人)安静( pacify的过去式和过去分词 ); 息怒; 抚慰; 在(有战争的地区、国家等)实现和平 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
56 civilized | |
a.有教养的,文雅的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
57 labors | |
v.努力争取(for)( labor的第三人称单数 );苦干;详细分析;(指引擎)缓慢而困难地运转 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
58 celebrated | |
adj.有名的,声誉卓著的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
59 lasting | |
adj.永久的,永恒的;vbl.持续,维持 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
60 duel | |
n./v.决斗;(双方的)斗争 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
61 martyrs | |
n.martyr的复数形式;烈士( martyr的名词复数 );殉道者;殉教者;乞怜者(向人诉苦以博取同情) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
62 ardent | |
adj.热情的,热烈的,强烈的,烈性的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
63 extraordinarily | |
adv.格外地;极端地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
64 amiable | |
adj.和蔼可亲的,友善的,亲切的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
65 inclination | |
n.倾斜;点头;弯腰;斜坡;倾度;倾向;爱好 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
66 monarchy | |
n.君主,最高统治者;君主政体,君主国 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
67 attainment | |
n.达到,到达;[常pl.]成就,造诣 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
68 monarchical | |
adj. 国王的,帝王的,君主的,拥护君主制的 =monarchic | |
参考例句: |
|
|
69 perseverance | |
n.坚持不懈,不屈不挠 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
70 systematic | |
adj.有系统的,有计划的,有方法的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
71 appropriation | |
n.拨款,批准支出 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
72 interpretation | |
n.解释,说明,描述;艺术处理 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
73 subsist | |
vi.生存,存在,供养 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
74 perpetuate | |
v.使永存,使永记不忘 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
75 diminution | |
n.减少;变小 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
76 previously | |
adv.以前,先前(地) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
77 withdrawn | |
vt.收回;使退出;vi.撤退,退出 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
78 lucid | |
adj.明白易懂的,清晰的,头脑清楚的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
79 physically | |
adj.物质上,体格上,身体上,按自然规律 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
80 permanently | |
adv.永恒地,永久地,固定不变地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
81 deteriorated | |
恶化,变坏( deteriorate的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
82 deterioration | |
n.退化;恶化;变坏 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
83 obedience | |
n.服从,顺从 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
84 plunged | |
v.颠簸( plunge的过去式和过去分词 );暴跌;骤降;突降 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
85 possessed | |
adj.疯狂的;拥有的,占有的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
86 pristine | |
adj.原来的,古时的,原始的,纯净的,无垢的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
87 retrieve | |
vt.重新得到,收回;挽回,补救;检索 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
88 insufficient | |
adj.(for,of)不足的,不够的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
89 insufficiently | |
adv.不够地,不能胜任地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
90 improperly | |
不正确地,不适当地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
91 solely | |
adv.仅仅,唯一地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
92 economists | |
n.经济学家,经济专家( economist的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
93 expenditure | |
n.(时间、劳力、金钱等)支出;使用,消耗 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
94 miserable | |
adj.悲惨的,痛苦的;可怜的,糟糕的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
95 oratorical | |
adj.演说的,雄辩的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
96 standing | |
n.持续,地位;adj.永久的,不动的,直立的,不流动的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
97 slumbering | |
微睡,睡眠(slumber的现在分词形式) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
98 accrues | |
v.增加( accrue的第三人称单数 );(通过自然增长)产生;获得;(使钱款、债务)积累 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
99 Augmented | |
adj.增音的 动词augment的过去式和过去分词形式 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
100 toiling | |
长时间或辛苦地工作( toil的现在分词 ); 艰难缓慢地移动,跋涉 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
101 crouches | |
n.蹲着的姿势( crouch的名词复数 )v.屈膝,蹲伏( crouch的第三人称单数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
102 surfeited | |
v.吃得过多( surfeit的过去式和过去分词 );由于过量而厌腻 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
103 tenant | |
n.承租人;房客;佃户;v.租借,租用 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
104 fraught | |
adj.充满…的,伴有(危险等)的;忧虑的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
105 hatred | |
n.憎恶,憎恨,仇恨 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
106 unnatural | |
adj.不自然的;反常的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
欢迎访问英文小说网 |