From the New York Packet. Friday, February 8, 1788.
MADISON
To the People of the State of New York:
FROM the more general inquiries1 pursued in the four last papers, I pass on to a more particular examination of the several parts of the government. I shall begin with the House of Representatives.
The first view to be taken of this part of the government relates to the qualifications of the electors and the elected. Those of the former are to be the same with those of the electors of the most numerous branch of the State legislatures. The definition of the right of suffrage2 is very justly regarded as a fundamental article of republican government. It was incumbent3 on the convention, therefore, to define and establish this right in the Constitution. To have left it open for the occasional regulation of the Congress, would have been improper4 for the reason just mentioned. To have submitted it to the legislative5 discretion6 of the States, would have been improper for the same reason; and for the additional reason that it would have rendered too dependent on the State governments that branch of the federal government which ought to be dependent on the people alone. To have reduced the different qualifications in the different States to one uniform rule, would probably have been as dissatisfactory to some of the States as it would have been difficult to the convention. The provision made by the convention appears, therefore, to be the best that lay within their option. It must be satisfactory to every State, because it is conformable to the standard already established, or which may be established, by the State itself. It will be safe to the United States, because, being fixed7 by the State constitutions, it is not alterable by the State governments, and it cannot be feared that the people of the States will alter this part of their constitutions in such a manner as to abridge8 the rights secured to them by the federal Constitution.
The qualifications of the elected, being less carefully and properly defined by the State constitutions, and being at the same time more susceptible9 of uniformity, have been very properly considered and regulated by the convention. A representative of the United States must be of the age of twenty-five years; must have been seven years a citizen of the United States; must, at the time of his election, be an inhabitant of the State he is to represent; and, during the time of his service, must be in no office under the United States. Under these reasonable limitations, the door of this part of the federal government is open to merit of every description, whether native or adoptive, whether young or old, and without regard to poverty or wealth, or to any particular profession of religious faith.
The term for which the representatives are to be elected falls under a second view which may be taken of this branch. In order to decide on the propriety10 of this article, two questions must be considered: first, whether biennial11 elections will, in this case, be safe; secondly12, whether they be necessary or useful.
First. As it is essential to liberty that the government in general should have a common interest with the people, so it is particularly essential that the branch of it under consideration should have an immediate13 dependence14 on, and an intimate sympathy with, the people. Frequent elections are unquestionably the only policy by which this dependence and sympathy can be effectually secured. But what particular degree of frequency may be absolutely necessary for the purpose, does not appear to be susceptible of any precise calculation, and must depend on a variety of circumstances with which it may be connected. Let us consult experience, the guide that ought always to be followed whenever it can be found.
The scheme of representation, as a substitute for a meeting of the citizens in person, being at most but very imperfectly known to ancient polity, it is in more modern times only that we are to expect instructive examples. And even here, in order to avoid a research too vague and diffusive15, it will be proper to confine ourselves to the few examples which are best known, and which bear the greatest analogy to our particular case. The first to which this character ought to be applied16, is the House of Commons in Great Britain. The history of this branch of the English Constitution, anterior17 to the date of Magna Charta, is too obscure to yield instruction. The very existence of it has been made a question among political antiquaries. The earliest records of subsequent date prove that parliaments were to SIT only every year; not that they were to be ELECTED every year. And even these annual sessions were left so much at the discretion of the monarch18, that, under various pretexts19, very long and dangerous intermissions were often contrived20 by royal ambition. To remedy this grievance21, it was provided by a statute22 in the reign23 of Charles II, that the intermissions should not be protracted24 beyond a period of three years. On the accession of William III, when a revolution took place in the government, the subject was still more seriously resumed, and it was declared to be among the fundamental rights of the people that parliaments ought to be held FREQUENTLY. By another statute, which passed a few years later in the same reign, the term "frequently," which had alluded25 to the triennial period settled in the time of Charles II, is reduced to a precise meaning, it being expressly enacted26 that a new parliament shall be called within three years after the termination of the former. The last change, from three to seven years, is well known to have been introduced pretty early in the present century, under on alarm for the Hanoverian succession. From these facts it appears that the greatest frequency of elections which has been deemed necessary in that kingdom, for binding27 the representatives to their constituents28, does not exceed a triennial return of them. And if we may argue from the degree of liberty retained even under septennial elections, and all the other vicious ingredients in the parliamentary constitution, we cannot doubt that a reduction of the period from seven to three years, with the other necessary reforms, would so far extend the influence of the people over their representatives as to satisfy us that biennial elections, under the federal system, cannot possibly be dangerous to the requisite29 dependence of the House of Representatives on their constituents.
Elections in Ireland, till of late, were regulated entirely30 by the discretion of the crown, and were seldom repeated, except on the accession of a new prince, or some other contingent31 event. The parliament which commenced with George II. was continued throughout his whole reign, a period of about thirty-five years. The only dependence of the representatives on the people consisted in the right of the latter to supply occasional vacancies32 by the election of new members, and in the chance of some event which might produce a general new election. The ability also of the Irish parliament to maintain the rights of their constituents, so far as the disposition33 might exist, was extremely shackled34 by the control of the crown over the subjects of their deliberation. Of late these shackles35, if I mistake not, have been broken; and octennial parliaments have besides been established. What effect may be produced by this partial reform, must be left to further experience. The example of Ireland, from this view of it, can throw but little light on the subject. As far as we can draw any conclusion from it, it must be that if the people of that country have been able under all these disadvantages to retain any liberty whatever, the advantage of biennial elections would secure to them every degree of liberty, which might depend on a due connection between their representatives and themselves.
Let us bring our inquiries nearer home. The example of these States, when British colonies, claims particular attention, at the same time that it is so well known as to require little to be said on it. The principle of representation, in one branch of the legislature at least, was established in all of them. But the periods of election were different. They varied36 from one to seven years. Have we any reason to infer, from the spirit and conduct of the representatives of the people, prior to the Revolution, that biennial elections would have been dangerous to the public liberties? The spirit which everywhere displayed itself at the commencement of the struggle, and which vanquished37 the obstacles to independence, is the best of proofs that a sufficient portion of liberty had been everywhere enjoyed to inspire both a sense of its worth and a zeal38 for its proper enlargement This remark holds good, as well with regard to the then colonies whose elections were least frequent, as to those whose elections were most frequent Virginia was the colony which stood first in resisting the parliamentary usurpations of Great Britain; it was the first also in espousing39, by public act, the resolution of independence. In Virginia, nevertheless, if I have not been misinformed, elections under the former government were septennial. This particular example is brought into view, not as a proof of any peculiar40 merit, for the priority in those instances was probably accidental; and still less of any advantage in SEPTENNIAL elections, for when compared with a greater frequency they are inadmissible; but merely as a proof, and I conceive it to be a very substantial proof, that the liberties of the people can be in no danger from BIENNIAL elections.
The conclusion resulting from these examples will be not a little strengthened by recollecting41 three circumstances. The first is, that the federal legislature will possess a part only of that supreme42 legislative authority which is vested completely in the British Parliament; and which, with a few exceptions, was exercised by the colonial assemblies and the Irish legislature. It is a received and well-founded maxim43, that where no other circumstances affect the case, the greater the power is, the shorter ought to be its duration; and, conversely, the smaller the power, the more safely may its duration be protracted. In the second place, it has, on another occasion, been shown that the federal legislature will not only be restrained by its dependence on its people, as other legislative bodies are, but that it will be, moreover, watched and controlled by the several collateral44 legislatures, which other legislative bodies are not. And in the third place, no comparison can be made between the means that will be possessed45 by the more permanent branches of the federal government for seducing46, if they should be disposed to seduce47, the House of Representatives from their duty to the people, and the means of influence over the popular branch possessed by the other branches of the government above cited. With less power, therefore, to abuse, the federal representatives can be less tempted48 on one side, and will be doubly watched on the other.
点击收听单词发音
1 inquiries | |
n.调查( inquiry的名词复数 );疑问;探究;打听 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
2 suffrage | |
n.投票,选举权,参政权 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
3 incumbent | |
adj.成为责任的,有义务的;现任的,在职的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
4 improper | |
adj.不适当的,不合适的,不正确的,不合礼仪的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
5 legislative | |
n.立法机构,立法权;adj.立法的,有立法权的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
6 discretion | |
n.谨慎;随意处理 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
7 fixed | |
adj.固定的,不变的,准备好的;(计算机)固定的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
8 abridge | |
v.删减,删节,节略,缩短 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
9 susceptible | |
adj.过敏的,敏感的;易动感情的,易受感动的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
10 propriety | |
n.正当行为;正当;适当 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
11 biennial | |
adj.两年一次的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
12 secondly | |
adv.第二,其次 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
13 immediate | |
adj.立即的;直接的,最接近的;紧靠的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
14 dependence | |
n.依靠,依赖;信任,信赖;隶属 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
15 diffusive | |
adj.散布性的,扩及的,普及的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
16 applied | |
adj.应用的;v.应用,适用 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
17 anterior | |
adj.较早的;在前的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
18 monarch | |
n.帝王,君主,最高统治者 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
19 pretexts | |
n.借口,托辞( pretext的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
20 contrived | |
adj.不自然的,做作的;虚构的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
21 grievance | |
n.怨愤,气恼,委屈 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
22 statute | |
n.成文法,法令,法规;章程,规则,条例 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
23 reign | |
n.统治时期,统治,支配,盛行;v.占优势 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
24 protracted | |
adj.拖延的;延长的v.拖延“protract”的过去式和过去分词 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
25 alluded | |
提及,暗指( allude的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
26 enacted | |
制定(法律),通过(法案)( enact的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
27 binding | |
有约束力的,有效的,应遵守的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
28 constituents | |
n.选民( constituent的名词复数 );成分;构成部分;要素 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
29 requisite | |
adj.需要的,必不可少的;n.必需品 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
30 entirely | |
ad.全部地,完整地;完全地,彻底地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
31 contingent | |
adj.视条件而定的;n.一组,代表团,分遣队 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
32 vacancies | |
n.空房间( vacancy的名词复数 );空虚;空白;空缺 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
33 disposition | |
n.性情,性格;意向,倾向;排列,部署 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
34 shackled | |
给(某人)带上手铐或脚镣( shackle的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
35 shackles | |
手铐( shackle的名词复数 ); 脚镣; 束缚; 羁绊 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
36 varied | |
adj.多样的,多变化的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
37 vanquished | |
v.征服( vanquish的过去式和过去分词 );战胜;克服;抑制 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
38 zeal | |
n.热心,热情,热忱 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
39 espousing | |
v.(决定)支持,拥护(目标、主张等)( espouse的现在分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
40 peculiar | |
adj.古怪的,异常的;特殊的,特有的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
41 recollecting | |
v.记起,想起( recollect的现在分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
42 supreme | |
adj.极度的,最重要的;至高的,最高的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
43 maxim | |
n.格言,箴言 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
44 collateral | |
adj.平行的;旁系的;n.担保品 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
45 possessed | |
adj.疯狂的;拥有的,占有的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
46 seducing | |
诱奸( seduce的现在分词 ); 勾引; 诱使堕落; 使入迷 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
47 seduce | |
vt.勾引,诱奸,诱惑,引诱 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
48 tempted | |
v.怂恿(某人)干不正当的事;冒…的险(tempt的过去分词) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
欢迎访问英文小说网 |