The produce, on the cottier system, being divided into two portions, rent, and the remuneration of the labourer; the one is evidently determined by the other. The labourer has whatever the landlord does not take: the condition of the labourer depends on the amount of rent. But rent, being regulated by competition, depends upon the relation between the demand for land, and the supply of it. The demand for land depends on the number of competitors, and the competitors are the whole rural population. The effect, therefore, of this tenure, is to bring the principle of population to act directly on the land, and not, as in England, on capital. Rent, in this state of things, depends on the proportion between population and land. As the land is a fixed10 quantity, while population has an unlimited11 power of increase; unless something checks that increase, the competition for land soon forces up rent to the highest point consistent with keeping the population alive. The effects, therefore, of cottier tenure depend on the extent to which the capacity of population to increase is controlled, either by custom, by individual prudence12, or by starvation and disease.
It would be an exaggeration to affirm, that cottier tenancy is absolutely incompatible13 with a prosperous condition of the labouring class. If we could suppose it to exist among a people to whom a high standard of comfort was habitual14; whose requirements were such, that they would not offer a higher rent for land than would leave them an ample subsistence, and whose moderate increase of numbers left no unemployed15 population to force up rents by competition, save when the increasing produce of the land from increase of skill would enable a higher rent to be paid without inconvenience; the cultivating class might be as well remunerated, might have as large a share of the necessaries and comforts of life, on this system of tenure as on any other. They would not, however, while their rents were arbitrary, enjoy any of the peculiar16 advantages which metayers on the Tuscan system derive5 from their connexion with the land. They would neither have the use of a capital belonging to their landlords, nor would the want of this be made up by the intense motives18 to bodily and mental exertion19 which act upon the peasant who has a permanent tenure. On the contrary, any increased value given to the land by the exertions20 of the tenant, would have no effect but to raise the rent against himself, either the next year, or at farthest when his lease expired. The landlords might have justice or good sense enough not to avail of the advantage which competition would give them; and different landlords would do so in different degrees. But it is never safe to expect that a class or body of men will act in opposition21 to their immediate22 pecuniary23 interest; and even a doubt on the subject would be almost as fatal as a certainty, for when a person is considering whether or not to undergo a present exertion or sacrifice for a comparatively remote future, the scale is turned by a very small probability that the fruits of the exertion or of the sacrifice will he taken away from him. The only safeguard against these uncertainties24 would be the growth of a custom, insuring a permanence of tenure in the same occupant, without liability to any other increase of rent than might happen to be sanctioned by the general sentiments of the community. The Ulster tenant-right is such a custom. The very considerable sums which outgoing tenants obtain from their successors, for the goodwill25 of their farms,1 in the first place actually limit the competition for land to persons who have such sums to offer: while the same fact also proves that full advantage is not taken by the landlord of even that more limited competition, since the landlord’s rent does not amount to the whole of what the incoming tenant not only offers but actually pays. He does so in the full confidence that the rent will not be raised; and for this he has the guarantee of a custom, not recognised by law, but deriving26 its binding27 force from another sanction, perfectly28 well understood in Ireland.2 Without one or other of these supports, a custom limiting the rent of land is not likely to grow up in any progressive community. If wealth and population were stationary29, rent also would generally be stationary, and after remaining a long time unaltered, would probably come to be considered unalterable. But all progress in wealth and population tends to a rise of rents. Under a metayer system there is an established mode in which the owner of land is sure of participating in the increased produce drawn30 from it. But on the cottier system he can only do so by a readjustment of the contract, while that readjustment, in a progressive community, would almost always be to his advantage. His interest, therefore, is decidedly opposed to the growth of any custom commuting31 rent into a fixed demand.
§2. Where the amount of rent is not limited, either by law or custom, a cottier system has the disadvantages of the worst metayer system, with scarcely any of the advantages by which, in the best forms of that tenure, they are compensated32. It is scarcely possible that cottier agriculture should be other than miserable34. There is not the same necessity that the condition of the cultivators should be so. Since by a sufficient restraint on population competition for land could be kept down, and extreme poverty prevented; habits of prudence and a high standard of comfort, once established, would have a fair chance of maintaining themselves: though even in these favourable35 circumstances the motives to prudence would be considerably36 weaker than in the case of metayers, protected by custom (like those of Tuscany) from being deprived of their farms: since a metayer family, thus protected, could not be impoverished37 by any other improvident38 multiplication39 than their own, but a cottier family, however prudent40 and self-restraining, may have the rent raised against it by the consequences of the multiplication of other families. Any protection to the cottiers against this evil could only be derived from a salutary sentiment of duty or dignity, pervading41 the class. this source, however, they might derive considerable protection. If the habitual standard of requirement among the class were high, a young man might not choose to offer a rent which would leave him in a worse condition than the preceding tenant; or it might be the general custom, as it actually is in some countries, not to marry until a farm is vacant.
But it is not where a high standard of comfort has rooted itself in the habits of the labouring class, that we are ever called upon to consider the effects of a cottier system. That system is found only where the habitual requirements of the rural labourers are the lowest possible; where as long as they are not actually staring, they will multiply: and population is only checked by the diseases, and the shortness of life, consequent on insufficiency of merely physical necessaries. This was the state of the largest portion of the Irish peasantry. When a people have sunk into this state, and still more when they have been in it from time immemorial, the cottier system is an almost insuperable obstacle to their emerging from it. When the habits of the people are such that their increase is never checked hut by the impossibility of obtaining a bare support, and when this support can only be obtained from land, all stipulations and agreements respecting amount of rent are merely nominal42; the competition for land makes the tenants undertake to pay more than it is possible they should pay, and when they have paid all they can, more almost always remains43 due.
“As it may fairly be said of the Irish peasantry,” said Mr. Revans, the Secretary to the Irish Poor Law Enquiry Commission,3 “that every family which has not sufficient land to yield its food has one or more of its members supported by begging, it will easily be conceived that every endeavour is made by the peasantry to obtain small holdings, and that they are not influenced in their biddings by the fertility of the land, or by their ability to pay the rent, but solely44 by the offer which is most likely to gain them possession. The rents which they promise, they are almost invariably incapable45 of paying; and consequently they become indebted to those under whom they hold, almost as soon as they take possession. They give up, in the shape of rent, the whole produce of the land with the exception of a sufficiency of potatoes for a subsistence; but as this is rarely equal to the promised rent, they constantly have against them an increasing balance. In some cases, the largest quantity of produce which their holdings ever yielded, or which, under their system of tillage, they could in the most favourable seasons be made to yield, would not be equal to the rent bid; consequently, if the peasant fulfilled his engagement with his landlord, which he is rarely able to accomplish, he would till the ground for nothing, and give his landlord a premium46 for being allowed to till it. On the seacoast, fishermen, and in the northern counties those who have looms47, frequently pay more in rent than the market value of the whole produce of the land they hold. It might be supposed that they would be better without land under such circumstances. But fishing might fail during a week or two, and so might the demand for the produce of the loom48, when, did they not possess the land upon which their food is grown, they might starve. The full amount of the rent bid, however, is rarely paid. The peasant remains constantly in debt to his landlord; his miserable possessions-the wretched clothing of himself and of his family, the two or three stools, and the few pieces of crockery, which his wretched hovel contains, would not, if sold, liquidate49 the standing50 and generally accumulating debt. The peasantry are mostly a year in arrear51, and their excuse for not paying more is destitution52. Should the produce of the holding, in any year, be more than usually abundant, or should the peasant by any accident become possessed53 of any property, his comforts cannot be increased; he cannot indulge in better food, nor in a greater quantity of it. His furniture cannot be increased, neither can his wife or children be better clothed. The acquisition must go to the person under whom he holds. The accidental addition will enable him to reduce his arrear of rent, and thus to defer54 ejectment. But this must be the bound of his expectation.”
As an extreme instance of the intensity55 of competition for land, and of the monstrous56 height to which it occasionally forced up the nominal rent; we may cite from the evidence taken by Lord Devon’s Commission,4 a fact attested57 by Mr Hurly, Clerk of the Crown for Kerry. “I have known a tenant bid for a farm that I was perfectly well acquainted with, worth 50l. a year: I saw the competition get up to such an extent, that he was declared the tenant at 450l.”
§3. In such a condition, what can a tenant gain by any amount of industry or prudence, and what lose by any recklessness? If the landlord at any time exerted his full legal rights, the cottier would not be able even to live. If by extra exertion he doubled the produce of his bit of land, or if he prudently58 abstained59 from producing mouths to eat it up, his only gain would be to have more left to pay to his landlord; while, if he had twenty children, they would still be fed first, and the landlord could only take what was left. Almost alone amongst mankind the cottier is in this condition, that he can scarcely be either better or worse off by any act of his own. If he were industrious60 or prudent, nobody but his landlord would gain; if he is lazy or intemperate61, it is at his landlord’s expense. A situation more devoid62 of motives to either labour or self-command, imagination itself cannot conceive. The inducements of free human beings are taken away, and those of a slave not substituted. He has nothing to hope, and nothing to fear, except being dispossessed of his holding, and against this he protects himself by the ultima ratio of a defensive63 civil war. Rockism and Whiteboyism were the determination of a people who had nothing that could be called theirs but a daily meal of the lowest description of food, not to submit to being deprived of that for other people’s convenience.
Is it not, then, a bitter satire64 on the mode in which opinions are formed on the most important problems of human nature and life, to find public instructors65 of the greatest pretension66, imputing67 the backwardness of Irish industry, and the want of energy of the Irish people in improving their condition, to a peculiar indolence and insouciance68 in the Celtic race? Of all vulgar modes of escaping from the consideration of the effect of social and moral influences on the human mind, the most vulgar is that of attributing the diversities of conduct and character to inherent natural differences. What race would not be indolent and insouciant69 when things are so arranged, that they derive no advantage from forethought or exertion? If such are the arrangements in the midst of which they live and work, what wonder if the listlessness and indifference70 so engendered71 are not shaken off the first moment an opportunity offers when exertion would really be of use? It is very natural that a pleasure-loving and sensitively organized people like the Irish, should be less addicted72 to steady routine labour than the English, because life has more excitements for them independent of it; but they are not less fitted for it than their Celtic brethren the French, nor less so than the Tuscans, or the ancient Greeks. An excitable organization is precisely73 that in which, by adequate inducements, it is easiest to kindle74 a spirit of animated75 exertion. It speaks nothing against the capacities of industry in human beings, that they will not exert themselves without motive17. No labourers work harder, in England or America, than the Irish; but not under a cottier system.
§4. The multitudes who till the soil of India, are in a condition sufficiently76 analogous77 to the cottier system, and at the same time sufficiently different from it, to render the comparison of the two a source of some instruction. In most parts of India there are, and perhaps have always been, only two contracting parties, the landlord and the peasant: the landlord being generally the sovereign, except where he has, by a special instrument, conceded his rights to an individual, who becomes his representative. The payments, however, of the peasants, or ryots as they are termed, have seldom if ever been regulated, as in Ireland, by competition. Though the customs locally obtaining were infinitely78 various, and though practically no custom could be maintained against the sovereign’s will, there was always a rule of some sort common to a neighbourhood; the collector did not make his separate bargain with the peasant, but assessed each according to the rule adopted for the rest. The idea was thus kept up of a right of property in the tenant, or at all events, of a right to permanent possession; and the anomaly arose of a fixity of tenure in the peasant-farmer, co-existing with an arbitrary power of increasing the rent.
When the Mogul government substituted itself throughout the greater part of India for the Hindoo rulers, it proceeded on a different principle. A minute survey was made of the land, and upon that survey an assessment79 was founded, fixing the specific payment due to the government from each field. if this assessment had never been exceeded, the ryots would have been in the comparatively advantageous80 position of peasant-proprietors, subject to a heavy, but a fixed quit-rent. The absence, however, of any real protection against illegal extortions, rendered this improvement in their condition rather nominal than real; and, except during the occasional accident of a humane81 and vigorous local administrator82, the exactions had no practical limit but the inability of the ryot to pay more.
It was to this state of things that the English rulers of India succeeded; and they were, at an early period, struck with the importance of putting an end to this arbitrary character of the land-revenue, and imposing83 a fixed limit to the government demand. They did not attempt to go back to the Mogul valuation. it has been in general the very rational practice of the English Government in India, to pay little regard to what was laid down as the theory of the native institutions, but to inquire into the rights which existed and were respected in practice, and to protect and enlarge those. For a long time, however, it blundered grievously about matters of fact, and grossly misunderstood the usages and rights which it found existing. Its mistakes arose from the inability of ordinary minds to imagine a state of social relations fundamentally different from those with which they are practically familiar. England being accustomed to great estates and great landlords, the English rulers took it for granted that india must possess the like; and looking round for some set of people who might be taken for the objects of their search, they pitched upon a sort of tax-gatherers called zemindars. “The zemindar,” says the philosophical84 historian of India,5 “had some of the attributes which belong to a landowner; he collected the rents of a particular district, he governed the cultivators of that district, lived in comparative splendour, and his son succeeded him when he died. The zemindars, therefore, it was inferred without delay, were the proprietors of the soil, the landed nobility and gentry85 of India. It was not considered that the zemindars, though they collected the rents, did not keep them; but paid them all away with a small deduction86 to the government. It was not considered that if they governed the ryots, and in many respects exercised over them despotic power, they did not govern them as tenants of theirs, holding their lands either at will or by contract under them. The possession of the ryot was an hereditary87 possession; from which it was unlawful for the zemindar to displace him; for every farthing which the zemindar drew from the ryot, he was bound to account; and it was only by fraud, if, out of all that he collected, he retained an ana more than the small proportion which, as pay for collection, he was permitted to receive.”
“There was an opportunity in India,” continues the historian, “to which the history of the world presents not a parallel. Next after the sovereign, the immediate cultivators had, by far, the greatest portion of interest in the soil. For the rights (such as they were) of the zemindars, a complete compensation might have easily been made. The generous resolution was adopted, of sacrificing to the improvement of the country, the proprietary88 rights of the sovereign. The motives to improvement which property gives, and of which the power was so justly appreciated, might have been bestowed89 upon those upon whom they would have operated with a force incomparably greater than that with which they could operate upon any other class of men: they might have been bestowed upon those from whom alone, in every country, the principal improvements in agriculture must be derived, the immediate cultivators of the soil. And a measure worthy90 to be ranked among the noblest that ever were taken for the improvement of any country, might have helped to compensate33 the people of India for the miseries91 of that misgovernment which they had so long endured. But the legislators were English aristocrats92; and aristocratical prejudices prevailed.”
The measure proved a total failure, as to the main effects which its wellmeaning promoters expected from it. Unaccustomed to estimate the mode in which the operation of any given institution is modified even by such variety of circumstances as exists within a single kingdom, they battered93 themselves that they had created, throughout the Bengal provinces, English landlords, and it proved that they had only created irish ones. The new landed aristocracy disappointed every expectation built upon them. They did nothing for the improvement of their estates, but everything for their own ruin. The same pains not being taken, as had been taken in Ireland, to enable landlords to defy the consequences of their improvidence94, nearly the whole land of Bengal had to be sequestrated and sold, for debts or arrears95 of revenue, and in one generation most of the ancient zemindars had ceased to exist. Other families, mostly the descendants of Calcutta money dealers96, or of native officials who had enriched themselves under the British government, now occupy their place; and live as useless drones on the soil which has been given up to them. Whatever the government has sacrificed of its pecuniary claims, for the creation of such a class, has at the best been wasted.
In the parts of India into which the British rule has been more recently introduced, the blunder has been avoided of endowing a useless body of great landlords with gifts from the public revenue. In most parts of the Madras and in part of the Bombay Presidency97, the rent is paid directly to the government by the immediate cultivator. In the North–Western Provinces, the government makes its engagement with the village community collectively, determining the share to be paid by each individual, but holding them jointly98 responsible for each other’s default. But in the greater part of India, the immediate cultivators have not obtained a perpetuity of tenure at a fixed rent. The government manages the land on the principle on which a good Irish landlord manages his estate: not putting it up to competition, not asking the cultivators what they will promise to pay, but determining for itself what they can afford to pay, and defining its demand accordingly. In many districts a portion of the cultivators are considered as tenants of the rest, the government making its demand from those only (often a numerous body) who are looked upon as the successors of the original settlers or conquerors99 of the village. Sometimes the rent is fixed only for one year, sometimes for three or five; but the uniform tendency of present policy is towards long leases, extending, in the northern provinces of India, to a term of thirty years. This arrangement has not existed for a sufficient time to have shown by experience, how far the motives to improvement which the long lease creates in the minds of the cultivators, fall short of the influence of a perpetual settlement.6 But the two plans, of annual settlements and of short leases, are irrevocably condemned100. They can only be said to have succeeded, in comparison with the unlimited oppression which existed before. They are approved by nobody, and were never looked upon in any other light than as temporary arrangements, to be abandoned when a more complete knowledge of the capabilities101 of the count should afford data for something more permanent.
点击收听单词发音
1 appellation | |
n.名称,称呼 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
2 tenure | |
n.终身职位;任期;(土地)保有权,保有期 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
3 intervention | |
n.介入,干涉,干预 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
4 determined | |
adj.坚定的;有决心的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
5 derive | |
v.取得;导出;引申;来自;源自;出自 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
6 derived | |
vi.起源;由来;衍生;导出v.得到( derive的过去式和过去分词 );(从…中)得到获得;源于;(从…中)提取 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
7 tenant | |
n.承租人;房客;佃户;v.租借,租用 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
8 tenants | |
n.房客( tenant的名词复数 );佃户;占用者;占有者 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
9 proprietors | |
n.所有人,业主( proprietor的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
10 fixed | |
adj.固定的,不变的,准备好的;(计算机)固定的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
11 unlimited | |
adj.无限的,不受控制的,无条件的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
12 prudence | |
n.谨慎,精明,节俭 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
13 incompatible | |
adj.不相容的,不协调的,不相配的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
14 habitual | |
adj.习惯性的;通常的,惯常的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
15 unemployed | |
adj.失业的,没有工作的;未动用的,闲置的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
16 peculiar | |
adj.古怪的,异常的;特殊的,特有的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
17 motive | |
n.动机,目的;adv.发动的,运动的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
18 motives | |
n.动机,目的( motive的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
19 exertion | |
n.尽力,努力 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
20 exertions | |
n.努力( exertion的名词复数 );费力;(能力、权力等的)运用;行使 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
21 opposition | |
n.反对,敌对 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
22 immediate | |
adj.立即的;直接的,最接近的;紧靠的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
23 pecuniary | |
adj.金钱的;金钱上的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
24 uncertainties | |
无把握( uncertainty的名词复数 ); 不确定; 变化不定; 无把握、不确定的事物 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
25 goodwill | |
n.善意,亲善,信誉,声誉 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
26 deriving | |
v.得到( derive的现在分词 );(从…中)得到获得;源于;(从…中)提取 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
27 binding | |
有约束力的,有效的,应遵守的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
28 perfectly | |
adv.完美地,无可非议地,彻底地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
29 stationary | |
adj.固定的,静止不动的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
30 drawn | |
v.拖,拉,拔出;adj.憔悴的,紧张的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
31 commuting | |
交换(的) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
32 compensated | |
补偿,报酬( compensate的过去式和过去分词 ); 给(某人)赔偿(或赔款) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
33 compensate | |
vt.补偿,赔偿;酬报 vi.弥补;补偿;抵消 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
34 miserable | |
adj.悲惨的,痛苦的;可怜的,糟糕的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
35 favourable | |
adj.赞成的,称赞的,有利的,良好的,顺利的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
36 considerably | |
adv.极大地;相当大地;在很大程度上 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
37 impoverished | |
adj.穷困的,无力的,用尽了的v.使(某人)贫穷( impoverish的过去式和过去分词 );使(某物)贫瘠或恶化 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
38 improvident | |
adj.不顾将来的,不节俭的,无远见的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
39 multiplication | |
n.增加,增多,倍增;增殖,繁殖;乘法 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
40 prudent | |
adj.谨慎的,有远见的,精打细算的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
41 pervading | |
v.遍及,弥漫( pervade的现在分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
42 nominal | |
adj.名义上的;(金额、租金)微不足道的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
43 remains | |
n.剩余物,残留物;遗体,遗迹 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
44 solely | |
adv.仅仅,唯一地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
45 incapable | |
adj.无能力的,不能做某事的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
46 premium | |
n.加付款;赠品;adj.高级的;售价高的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
47 looms | |
n.织布机( loom的名词复数 )v.隐约出现,阴森地逼近( loom的第三人称单数 );隐约出现,阴森地逼近 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
48 loom | |
n.织布机,织机;v.隐现,(危险、忧虑等)迫近 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
49 liquidate | |
v.偿付,清算,扫除;整理,破产 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
50 standing | |
n.持续,地位;adj.永久的,不动的,直立的,不流动的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
51 arrear | |
n.欠款 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
52 destitution | |
n.穷困,缺乏,贫穷 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
53 possessed | |
adj.疯狂的;拥有的,占有的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
54 defer | |
vt.推迟,拖延;vi.(to)遵从,听从,服从 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
55 intensity | |
n.强烈,剧烈;强度;烈度 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
56 monstrous | |
adj.巨大的;恐怖的;可耻的,丢脸的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
57 attested | |
adj.经检验证明无病的,经检验证明无菌的v.证明( attest的过去式和过去分词 );证实;声称…属实;使宣誓 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
58 prudently | |
adv. 谨慎地,慎重地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
59 abstained | |
v.戒(尤指酒),戒除( abstain的过去式和过去分词 );弃权(不投票) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
60 industrious | |
adj.勤劳的,刻苦的,奋发的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
61 intemperate | |
adj.无节制的,放纵的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
62 devoid | |
adj.全无的,缺乏的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
63 defensive | |
adj.防御的;防卫的;防守的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
64 satire | |
n.讽刺,讽刺文学,讽刺作品 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
65 instructors | |
指导者,教师( instructor的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
66 pretension | |
n.要求;自命,自称;自负 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
67 imputing | |
v.把(错误等)归咎于( impute的现在分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
68 insouciance | |
n.漠不关心 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
69 insouciant | |
adj.不在意的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
70 indifference | |
n.不感兴趣,不关心,冷淡,不在乎 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
71 engendered | |
v.产生(某形势或状况),造成,引起( engender的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
72 addicted | |
adj.沉溺于....的,对...上瘾的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
73 precisely | |
adv.恰好,正好,精确地,细致地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
74 kindle | |
v.点燃,着火 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
75 animated | |
adj.生气勃勃的,活跃的,愉快的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
76 sufficiently | |
adv.足够地,充分地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
77 analogous | |
adj.相似的;类似的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
78 infinitely | |
adv.无限地,无穷地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
79 assessment | |
n.评价;评估;对财产的估价,被估定的金额 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
80 advantageous | |
adj.有利的;有帮助的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
81 humane | |
adj.人道的,富有同情心的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
82 administrator | |
n.经营管理者,行政官员 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
83 imposing | |
adj.使人难忘的,壮丽的,堂皇的,雄伟的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
84 philosophical | |
adj.哲学家的,哲学上的,达观的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
85 gentry | |
n.绅士阶级,上层阶级 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
86 deduction | |
n.减除,扣除,减除额;推论,推理,演绎 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
87 hereditary | |
adj.遗传的,遗传性的,可继承的,世袭的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
88 proprietary | |
n.所有权,所有的;独占的;业主 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
89 bestowed | |
赠给,授予( bestow的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
90 worthy | |
adj.(of)值得的,配得上的;有价值的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
91 miseries | |
n.痛苦( misery的名词复数 );痛苦的事;穷困;常发牢骚的人 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
92 aristocrats | |
n.贵族( aristocrat的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
93 battered | |
adj.磨损的;v.连续猛击;磨损 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
94 improvidence | |
n.目光短浅 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
95 arrears | |
n.到期未付之债,拖欠的款项;待做的工作 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
96 dealers | |
n.商人( dealer的名词复数 );贩毒者;毒品贩子;发牌者 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
97 presidency | |
n.总统(校长,总经理)的职位(任期) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
98 jointly | |
ad.联合地,共同地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
99 conquerors | |
征服者,占领者( conqueror的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
100 condemned | |
adj. 被责难的, 被宣告有罪的 动词condemn的过去式和过去分词 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
101 capabilities | |
n.能力( capability的名词复数 );可能;容量;[复数]潜在能力 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
欢迎访问英文小说网 |