But what constitutes the measure of our prosperity, or of our wealth? Is it the result of the effort? or is it the effort itself? A relation always subsists2 between the effort employed and the result obtained. Progress consists in the relative enhancement of the second or of the first term of this relation.
Both theses have been maintained; and in political economy they have divided the region of opinion and of thought.
According to the first system, wealth is the result of labour, increasing as the relative proportion of result to effort increases. Absolute perfection, of which God is the type, consists in the infinite distance interposed between the two terms—in this sense, effort is nil3, result infinite.
The second system teaches that it is the effort itself which constitutes the measure of wealth. To make progress is to increase the relative proportion which effort bears to result. The ideal of this system may be found in the sterile4 and eternal efforts of Sisyphus.*
The first system naturally welcomes everything which tends to diminish pains and augment5 products; powerful machinery6 which increases the forces of man, exchange which allows him to derive7 greater advantage from natural agents distributed in various proportions over the face of the earth, intelligence which discovers, experience which proves, competition which stimulates8, etc.
Logically, the second invokes9 everything which has the effect of increasing pains and diminishing products; privileges, monopolies, restrictions10, prohibitions12, suppression of machinery, sterility13, etc.
It is well to remark that the universal practice of mankind always points to the principle of the first system. We have never seen, we shall never see, a man who labours in any department, be he agriculturist, manufacturer, merchant, artificer, soldier, author, or philosopher, who does not devote all the powers of his mind to work better, to work with more rapidity, to work more economically—in a word, to effect more with less.
The opposite doctrine14 is in favour only with theorists, deputies, journalists, statesmen, ministers—men, in short, born to make experiments on the social body.
* For this reason, and for the sake of conciseness15, the
reader will pardon us for designating this system in the
sequel by the name of sisyphism.
At the same time, we may observe, that in what concerns themselves personally, they act as every one else does, on the principle of obtaining from labour the greatest possible amount of useful results.
Perhaps I may be thought to exaggerate, and that there are no true sisyphists.
If it be argued that in practice they do not press their principle to its most extreme consequences, I willingly grant it. This is always the case when one sets out with a false principle. Such a principle soon leads to results so absurd and so mischievous16 that we are obliged to stop short. This is the reason why practical industry never admits sisyphism; punishment would follow error too closely not to expose it. But in matters of speculation17, such as theorists and statesmen deal in, one may pursue a false principle a long time before discovering its falsity by the complicated consequences to which men were formerly18 strangers; and when at last its falsity is found out, the authors take refuge in the opposite principle, turn round, contradict themselves, and seek their justification19 in a modern maxim20 of incomparable absurdity22: in political economy, there is no inflexible23 rule, no absolute principle.
Let us see, then, if these two opposite principles which I have just described do not predominate by turns, the one in practical industry, the other in industrial legislation.
I have already noticed the saying of M. Bugeaud (that "when bread is dear, agriculturists become rich"); but in M. Bugeaud are embodied24 two separate characters, the agriculturist and the legislator.
As an agriculturist, M. Bugeaud directs all his efforts to two ends,—to save labour, and obtain cheap bread. When he prefers a good plough to a bad one; when he improves his pastures; when, in order to pulverize25 the soil, he substitutes as much as possible the action of the atmosphere for that of the harrow and the hoe; when he calls to his aid all the processes of which science and experiment have proved the efficacy,—he has but one object in view, viz., to diminish the proportion of effort to result. We have indeed no other test of the ability of a cultivator, and the perfection of his processes, than to measure to what extent they have lessened26 the one and added to the other. And as all the farmers in the world act upon this principle, we may assert that the effort of mankind at large is to obtain, for their own benefit undoubtedly28, bread and all other products cheaper, to lessen27 the labour needed to procure29 a given quantity of what they want.
This incontestable tendency of mankind once established, should, it would seem, reveal to the legislator the true principle, and point out to him in what way he should aid industry (in as far as it falls within his province to aid it); for it would be absurd to assert that human laws should run counter to the laws of Providence30.
And yet we have heard M. Bugeaud, as a deputy, exclaim: "I understand nothing of this theory of cheapness; I should like better to see bread dearer and labour more abundant." And following out this doctrine, the deputy of the Dordogne votes legislative31 measures, the effect of which is to hamper32 exchanges, for the very reason that they procure us indirectly33 what direct production could not procure us but at greater expense.
Now, it is very evident that M. Bugeaud's principle as a deputy is directly opposed to the principle on which he acts as an agriculturist. To act consistently, he should vote against all legislative restriction11, or else import into his farming operations the principle which he proclaims from the tribune. We should then see him sow his corn in his most sterile fields, for in this way he would succeed in working much to obtain little. We should see him throwing aside the plough, since hand-culture would satisfy his double wish for dearer bread and more abundant labour.
It has also for its avowed object, and its acknowledged effect, to cause dearness, which means simply scarcity35 of products; so that, carried out to its extreme limits, it is pure sisyphism, such as we have defined it,—labour infinite, product nil.
Baron36 Charles Dupin, the light of the peerage, it is said, on economic science, accuses railways of injuring navigation; and it is certain that it is of the nature of a more perfect, to restrict the use of a less perfect means of conveyance37. But railways cannot hurt navigation except by attracting traffic; and they cannot attract traffic but by conveying goods and passengers more cheaply; and they cannot convey them more cheaply but by diminishing the proportion which the effort employed bears to the result obtained, seeing that that is the very thing which constitutes cheapness. When, then, Baron Dupin deplores38 this diminution39 of the labour employed to effect a given result, it is the doctrine of sisyphism which he preaches. Logically, since he prefers the ship to the rail, he should prefer the cart to the ship, the pack-saddle to the cart, and the pannier to all other known means of conveyance, for it is the latter which exacts the most labour with the least result.
"Labour constitutes the wealth of a people," said M. de Saint-Cricq, that Minister of Commerce who has imposed so many restrictions upon trade. We must not suppose that this was an elliptical expression, meaning, "The results of labour constitute the wealth of a people." No, this economist40 distinctly intended to affirm that it is the intensity41 of labour which is the measure of wealth, and the proof of it is, that from consequence to consequence, from one restriction to another, he induced France (and in this he thought he was doing her good) to expend42 double the amount of labour, in order, for example, to provide herself with an equal quantity of iron. In England, iron was then at eight francs, while in France it cost sixteen francs. Taking a day's labour at one franc, it is clear that France could, by means of exchange, procure a quintal of iron by subtracting eight days' work from the aggregate43 national labour. In consequence of the restrictive measures of M. de Saint-Cricq, France was obliged to expend sixteen days' labour in order to provide herself with a quintal of iron by direct production. Double the labour for the same satisfaction, hence double the wealth. Then it follows that wealth is not measured by the result, but by the intensity of the labour. Is not this sisyphism in all its purity?
And in order that there may be no mistake as to his meaning, the Minister takes care afterwards to explain more fully44 his ideas; and as he had just before called the intensity of labour wealthy he goes on to call the more abundant results of that labour, or the more abundant supply of things proper to satisfy our wants, poverty. "Everywhere," he says, "machinery has taken the place of manual labour; everywhere production superabounds; everywhere the equilibrium45 between the faculty46 of producing, and the means of consuming, is destroyed." We see, then, to what, in M. de Saint-Cricq's estimation, the critical situation of the country was owing—it was to having produced too much, and her labour being too intelligent, and too fruitful. We were too well fed, too well clothed, too well provided with everything; a too rapid production surpassed all our desires. It was necessary, then, to put a stop to the evil, and for that purpose, to force us, by restrictions, to labour more in order to produce less.
I have referred likewise to the opinions of another Minister of Commerce, M. d'Argout. They deserve to be dwelt upon for an instant. Desiring to strike a formidable blow at beet-root culture, he says, "Undoubtedly, the cultivation47 of beet-root is useful, but this utility is limited. The developments attributed to it are exaggerated. To be convinced of this, it is sufficient to observe that this culture will be necessarily confined within the limits of consumption. Double, triple, if you will, the present consumption of France, you will always find that a very trifling48 portion of the soil will satisfy the requirements of that consumption." (This is surely rather a singular subject of complaint!) "Do you desire proof of this? How many hectares had we under beet-root in 1828? 3130, which is equivalent to 1-10, 540th of our arable21 land. At the present time, when indigenous49 sugar supplies one-third of our consumption, how much land is devoted50 to that culture? 16,700 hectares, or 1-1978th of the arable land, or 45 centiares in each commune. Suppose indigenous sugar already supplied our whole consumption, we should have only 48,000 hectares under beet-root, or 1-689th of the arable land."*
There are two things to be remarked upon in this citation—the facts and the doctrine. The facts tend to prove that little land, little capital, and little labour are required to produce a large quantity of sugar, and that each commune of France would be abundantly provided by devoting to beet-root cultivation one hectare of its soil. The doctrine consists in regarding this circumstance as adverse51, and in seeing in the very power and fertility of the new industry, a limit to its utility.
* It is fair to M. d'Argout to say that he put this language
in the mouth of the adversaries52 of beet-root culture. But he
adopts it formally, and sanctions it besides, by the law
I do not mean to constitute myself here the defender54 of beet-root culture, or a judge of the strange facts advanced by M. d'Argout; * but it is worth while to scrutinize55 the doctrine of a statesman, to whom France for a long time entrusted56 the care of her agriculture and of her commerce.
I remarked in the outset that a variable relation exists between an industrial effort and its result; that absolute imperfection consists in an infinite effort without any result; absolute perfection in an unlimited57 result without any effort; and perfectibility in the progressive diminution of effort compared with the result.
But M. d'Argout tells us there is death where we think we perceive life, and that the importance of any branch of industry is in direct proportion to its powerlessness. What are we to expect, for instance, from the cultivation of beet-root? Do you not see that 48,000 hectares of land, with capital and manual labour in proportion, are sufficient to supply all France with sugar? Then, this is a branch of industry of limited utility; limited, of course, with reference to the amount of labour which it demands, the only way in which, according to the ex-Minister, any branch of industry can be useful. This utility would be still more limited, if, owing to the fertility of the soil, and the richness of the beet-root, we could reap from 24,000 hectares, what at present we only obtain from 48,000. Oh! were only twenty times, a hundred times, more land, capital, and labour necessary to yield us the same result, so much the better. We might build some hopes on this new branch of industry, and it would be worthy58 of state protection, for it would offer a vast field to our national industry. But to produce much with little! that is a bad example, and it is time for the law to interfere59.
* Supposing that 48,000 or 50,000 hectares were sufficient
to supply the present consumption, it would require 150,000
for triple that consumption, which M. d'Argout admits as
possible. Moreover, if beet-root entered into a six years'
hectares, or 1-38th of the arable land.
But what is true with regard to sugar, cannot be otherwise with regard to bread. If, then, the utility of any branch of industry is to be estimated not by the amount of satisfactions it is fitted to procure us with a determinate amount of labour, but, on the contrary, by the amount of labour which it exacts in order to yield us a determinate amount of satisfactions, what we ought evidently to desire is, that each acre of land should yield less corn, and each grain of com less nourishment61; in other words, that our land should be comparatively barren; for then the quantity of land, capital, and manual labour that would be required for the maintenance of our population would be much more considerable; we could then say that the demand for human labour would be in direct proportion to this barrenness. The aspirations62 of MM. Bugeaud, Saint-Cricq, Dupin, and d'Argout, would then be satisfied; bread would be dear, labour abundant, and France rich—rich at least in the sense in which these gentlemen understand the word.
What we should desire also is, that human intelligence should be enfeebled or extinguished; for, as long as it survives, it will be continually endeavouring to augment the proportion which the end bears to the means, and which the product bears to the labour. It is in that precisely63 that intelligence consists.
Thus, it appears that sisyphism has been the doctrine of all the men who have been intrusted with our industrial destinies. It would be unfair to reproach them with it. This principle guides Ministers only because it is predominant in the Chambers64; and it predominates in the Chambers only because it is sent there by the electoral body, and the electoral body is imbued65 with it only because public opinion is saturated66 with it.
I think it right to repeat here that I do not accuse men such as MM. Bugeaud, Dupin, Saint-Cricq, and d'Argout of being absolutely and under all circumstances sisyphists. They are certainly not so in their private transactions; for in these they always desire to obtain by way of exchange what would cost them dearer to procure by direct production; but I affirm they are sisyphists when they hinder the country from doing the same thing.

点击
收听单词发音

1
faculties
![]() |
|
n.能力( faculty的名词复数 );全体教职员;技巧;院 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
2
subsists
![]() |
|
v.(靠很少的钱或食物)维持生活,生存下去( subsist的第三人称单数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
3
nil
![]() |
|
n.无,全无,零 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
4
sterile
![]() |
|
adj.不毛的,不孕的,无菌的,枯燥的,贫瘠的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
5
augment
![]() |
|
vt.(使)增大,增加,增长,扩张 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
6
machinery
![]() |
|
n.(总称)机械,机器;机构 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
7
derive
![]() |
|
v.取得;导出;引申;来自;源自;出自 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
8
stimulates
![]() |
|
v.刺激( stimulate的第三人称单数 );激励;使兴奋;起兴奋作用,起刺激作用,起促进作用 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
9
invokes
![]() |
|
v.援引( invoke的第三人称单数 );行使(权利等);祈求救助;恳求 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
10
restrictions
![]() |
|
约束( restriction的名词复数 ); 管制; 制约因素; 带限制性的条件(或规则) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
11
restriction
![]() |
|
n.限制,约束 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
12
prohibitions
![]() |
|
禁令,禁律( prohibition的名词复数 ); 禁酒; 禁例 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
13
sterility
![]() |
|
n.不生育,不结果,贫瘠,消毒,无菌 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
14
doctrine
![]() |
|
n.教义;主义;学说 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
15
conciseness
![]() |
|
n.简洁,简短 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
16
mischievous
![]() |
|
adj.调皮的,恶作剧的,有害的,伤人的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
17
speculation
![]() |
|
n.思索,沉思;猜测;投机 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
18
formerly
![]() |
|
adv.从前,以前 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
19
justification
![]() |
|
n.正当的理由;辩解的理由 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
20
maxim
![]() |
|
n.格言,箴言 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
21
arable
![]() |
|
adj.可耕的,适合种植的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
22
absurdity
![]() |
|
n.荒谬,愚蠢;谬论 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
23
inflexible
![]() |
|
adj.不可改变的,不受影响的,不屈服的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
24
embodied
![]() |
|
v.表现( embody的过去式和过去分词 );象征;包括;包含 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
25
pulverize
![]() |
|
v.研磨成粉;摧毁 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
26
lessened
![]() |
|
减少的,减弱的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
27
lessen
![]() |
|
vt.减少,减轻;缩小 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
28
undoubtedly
![]() |
|
adv.确实地,无疑地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
29
procure
![]() |
|
vt.获得,取得,促成;vi.拉皮条 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
30
providence
![]() |
|
n.深谋远虑,天道,天意;远见;节约;上帝 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
31
legislative
![]() |
|
n.立法机构,立法权;adj.立法的,有立法权的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
32
hamper
![]() |
|
vt.妨碍,束缚,限制;n.(有盖的)大篮子 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
33
indirectly
![]() |
|
adv.间接地,不直接了当地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
34
avowed
![]() |
|
adj.公开声明的,承认的v.公开声明,承认( avow的过去式和过去分词) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
35
scarcity
![]() |
|
n.缺乏,不足,萧条 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
36
baron
![]() |
|
n.男爵;(商业界等)巨头,大王 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
37
conveyance
![]() |
|
n.(不动产等的)转让,让与;转让证书;传送;运送;表达;(正)运输工具 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
38
deplores
![]() |
|
v.悲叹,痛惜,强烈反对( deplore的第三人称单数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
39
diminution
![]() |
|
n.减少;变小 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
40
economist
![]() |
|
n.经济学家,经济专家,节俭的人 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
41
intensity
![]() |
|
n.强烈,剧烈;强度;烈度 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
42
expend
![]() |
|
vt.花费,消费,消耗 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
43
aggregate
![]() |
|
adj.总计的,集合的;n.总数;v.合计;集合 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
44
fully
![]() |
|
adv.完全地,全部地,彻底地;充分地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
45
equilibrium
![]() |
|
n.平衡,均衡,相称,均势,平静 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
46
faculty
![]() |
|
n.才能;学院,系;(学院或系的)全体教学人员 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
47
cultivation
![]() |
|
n.耕作,培养,栽培(法),养成 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
48
trifling
![]() |
|
adj.微不足道的;没什么价值的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
49
indigenous
![]() |
|
adj.土产的,土生土长的,本地的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
50
devoted
![]() |
|
adj.忠诚的,忠实的,热心的,献身于...的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
51
adverse
![]() |
|
adj.不利的;有害的;敌对的,不友好的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
52
adversaries
![]() |
|
n.对手,敌手( adversary的名词复数 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
53
justify
![]() |
|
vt.证明…正当(或有理),为…辩护 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
54
defender
![]() |
|
n.保卫者,拥护者,辩护人 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
55
scrutinize
![]() |
|
n.详细检查,细读 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
56
entrusted
![]() |
|
v.委托,托付( entrust的过去式和过去分词 ) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
57
unlimited
![]() |
|
adj.无限的,不受控制的,无条件的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
58
worthy
![]() |
|
adj.(of)值得的,配得上的;有价值的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
59
interfere
![]() |
|
v.(in)干涉,干预;(with)妨碍,打扰 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
60
rotation
![]() |
|
n.旋转;循环,轮流 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
61
nourishment
![]() |
|
n.食物,营养品;营养情况 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
62
aspirations
![]() |
|
强烈的愿望( aspiration的名词复数 ); 志向; 发送气音; 发 h 音 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
63
precisely
![]() |
|
adv.恰好,正好,精确地,细致地 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
64
chambers
![]() |
|
n.房间( chamber的名词复数 );(议会的)议院;卧室;会议厅 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
65
imbued
![]() |
|
v.使(某人/某事)充满或激起(感情等)( imbue的过去式和过去分词 );使充满;灌输;激发(强烈感情或品质等) | |
参考例句: |
|
|
66
saturated
![]() |
|
a.饱和的,充满的 | |
参考例句: |
|
|
欢迎访问英文小说网 |